MAXIMUM ECONOMIC YIELD AND ITS IMPORTANCE IN FISHERIES MANAGEMENT

Similar documents
Economics, fisheries and responsible fisheries management

AGEC 604 Natural Resource Economics

A Dynamic Optimization Model for Marine Fisheries Management in Kerala

SMALL-SCALE FISHERIES MANAGEMENT FOR TRADITIONAL SHRIMP FISHERMEN : A BIONOMICS GOMPERTS-FOX MODEL

Maximising net economic returns in mixed fisheries: how many species do we need to control?

Comment on What Restoration Schemes Can Do. Or, Getting It Right Without Fisheries Transferable Quotas

The race for boats. Christian Mullon (IRD-France), Charles Mullon (UFL- Switzerland)

A Model for Tuna-Fishery Policy Analysis: Combining System Dynamics and Game Theory Approach

Management advisory for the Bay of Bengal hilsa fishery June 2012

Policy Instruments for Fisheries Management and the Concept of Fisheries Refugia

Categories of fish. 1. Demersal: live on or near the ocean floor (cod, halibut, flounder, hake, shrimp, and shelfish)

MAXIMUM ECONOMIC YIELD AND RESOURCE ALLOCATION IN THE SPINY LOBSTER INDUSTRY* Joel S. Williams and Fred J. Prochaska

CHAPTER 12: FISHERIES

Fishing Capacity and Efficient Fleet Configuration for the Tuna Purse Seine Fishery in the Eastern Pacific Ocean: An Economic Approach

Whiting (Merlangius merlangus) in Division 6.a (West of Scotland)

AUTHOR: TITLE: SOURCE: THE FISHERY

Economic benefits of healthy fisheries.

Testimony of Ray Hilborn to U.S. Senate subcommittee.

Plaice (Pleuronectes platessa) in Division 7.e (western English Channel)

Economic efficiency of mechanised fishing in Tamil Nadu a case study in Chennai

A BIOECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF SUSTAINABILITY OF MARINE FISH PRODUCTiuN IN KERALA

Common Resource Problem-Fishing

Sustainable Use and Conservation of Marine Living Resources

establishing further emergency measures in 2017 and 2018 for small pelagic stocks in the Adriatic Sea (GSA 17 and GSA 18)

Advice June Sole in Division IIIa and Subdivisions (Skagerrak, Kattegat, and the Belts)

The primary purpose of the TFF is to help promote a healthy farm tenanted sector in Scotland. It aims to fulfil this purpose by:

Revisions to the National Standard 1 Guidelines:

Sustainable fisheries and aquaculture in the Mediterranean Pêcheries et aquaculture soutenables en Méditerranée

WORKING GROUP ON STOCK ASSESSMENTS 5 TH MEETING DOCUMENT SAR-5-08 TARGET SIZE FOR THE TUNA FLEET IN THE EASTERN PACIFIC OCEAN

MEFISTO PREPARED APPLICATIONS MODELLING FISHERIES MANAGEMENT STRATEGIES IN THE MEDITERRANEAN

Paper prepared by the Secretariat

Keywords: Rights-Based Management, Fisheries, Voluntary, Experiment, Chignik

Policy Forum Article. Three Pillars of Fisheries Policy. R. Quentin Grafton and Tom Kompas* Abstract. 1. Introduction

Using Fishermen s Expertise to Improve Fisheries Management

Sprat (Sprattus sprattus) in Subarea 4 (North Sea)

Introduction to population dynamics and stock assessments

Independent Economic Analysis Board. Review of the Estimated Economic Impacts of Salmon Fishing in Idaho. Task Number 99

Proposal for biomass and fishing mortality limit reference points based on reductions in recruitment. Mark N. Maunder and Richard B.

Spurdog (Squalus acanthias) in the Northeast Atlantic

The State of the Ocean and the impact of subsidies. Daniel Pauly Sea Around Us project Fisheries Centre, UBC

4.9 92,000. Healthy fisheries are good for business How better management of European fisheries will create jobs and improve the economy

REC.CM-GFCM/40/2016/4

Fish Conservation and Management

The State of World Fishery

RETROSPECTIVE ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF FRASER RIVER SOCKEYE SALMON FISHERY MANAGEMENT ABSTRACT

"Recommended Improvements for the Next Pacific Salmon Treaty"

Sustainable Fisheries for Future Generations The Fisheries White Paper

Why has the cod stock recovered in the North Sea?

Draft Discussion Document. May 27, 2016

OR DUNGENESS CRAB FISHERY:

The State of the World Marine Fisheries (II): Solutions for the World and Brazil Daniel Pauly Sea Around Us Fisheries Centre, UBC

FISHERIES MANAGEMENT UNDER SPECIES ALTERNATION: CASE OF THE PACIFIC PURSE SEINER OFF JAPAN

ICES Advisory Approach

EU request to ICES on in-year advice on haddock (Melanogrammus aeglefinus) in Division 7.a (Irish Sea)

Certification Determination. Louisiana Blue Crab Commercial Fishery

Cod (Gadus morhua) in subareas 1 and 2 (Northeast Arctic)

CHAPTER FIVE COST VOLUME PROFIT ANALYSIS OF DELHI METRO

Management of renewable resource harvesting

I. What is a Fishery? II. What is Fisheries Management? III. What is Fisheries Science? I. Brief history of the evolution of fisheries science.

Estimation and Analysis of Fish Catches by Category Based on Multidimensional Time Series Database on Sea Fishery in Greece

Florida's Spiny Lobster Trap Certificate Program

Glossary. Action point or trigger point or level

9. Resource rent as a central concept in fisheries management: The case of Namibia Overview. Case study (3)

Market Interactions between Aquaculture and Capture Fisheries: an Empirical Application to the Sockeye Salmon Fisheries in Bristol Bay, Alaska

AMBLYGASTER SIRM (WALBAUM) OFF THE NEGOMBO COAST

Sandeel (Ammodytes spp.) in Divisions IIIa, IVa, and IVb, SA 3 (Skagerrak and Kattegat, North and Central North Sea)

WESTERN MEDITERRANEAN

Food Chain. Marine Food Webs and Fisheries

SWG-11-JM-10. F Limit Reference Points about Preventing Recruitment Overfishing and its Uncertainty

Proposal for a COUNCIL REGULATION

INVESTING IN SUSTAINABLE FISHING CAN SPARK GLOBAL FISHERIES RECOVERY

Production economics of non mechanised fishing in the selected fish landing centres of Thoothukudi, Tamil Nadu

NEW WTO DISCIPLINES ON FISHING SUBSIDIES: OUTLINE OF A ROBUST SOLUTION (WWF DISCUSSION PAPER 29 APRIL 2003)

Economics of (un-)sustainability in global fisheries

3.3.2 Cod (Gadus morhua) in subareas 1 and 2 (Northeast Arctic)

NASCO Guidelines for the Management of Salmon Fisheries

More Food, More Jobs and More Money in the UK. Oceana s Recipe for Fish Recovery

Herring (Clupea harengus) in subdivisions and 32 (central Baltic Sea, excluding Gulf of Riga)

Catch allocation in a shared fishery with a minimally managed recreational sector *

Trawl fishery management of Eastern Arabian Sea

ICES Advice on fishing opportunities, catch, and effort Celtic Seas and Greater North Sea ecoregions Published 30 June 2016

BSAC recommendations for the fishery in the Baltic Sea in 2018

3.4.3 Advice June Barents Sea and Norwegian Sea Cod in Subareas I and II (Norwegian coastal waters cod)

Advice June 2014

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION. Fishing Opportunities for 2009 Policy Statement from the European Commission

BS thesis in Economics. Rights-based Management Systems in Fisheries

Retrenchment or Stagnation: Lessons from Japan s Lost Decades. Andrew Smithers. UK-Japan 21 st Century Group Conference 3 rd May, 2013

Fishing mortality in relation to highest yield. Fishing mortality in relation to agreed target

5. purse seines 3 000

Rent generation and dissipation in the Western Central Pacific tuna fishery. Michael Harte. July 2016

Could Welfare Optimality be Achieved with Extensive Data Information?

pfli ) f 'fhi H.r'\j,ijn''^

ICES Advice on fishing opportunities, catch, and effort Celtic Seas and Greater North Sea Ecoregions Published 24 October 2017

ECONOMY AND ENVIRONMENT PROGRAM FOR SOUTHEAST ASIA

7. Catch Balancing. 7.1 Catch Balancing

Assessment Summary Report Gulf of Mexico Red Snapper SEDAR 7

STRUCTURAL ADJUSTMENT AND REGULATION OF NORDIC FISHERIES UNTIL 2025

First Ever Estimate of Cod Fishery in 1850s Reveals 96% Decline on Scotian Shelf

Whiting (Merlangius merlangus) in Subarea 4 and Division 7.d (North Sea and eastern English Channel)

WHAT IS THE CODE OF CONDUCT FOR RESPONSIBLE FISHERIES?

Transcription:

MAXIMUM ECONOMIC YIELD AND ITS IMPORTANCE IN FISHERIES MANAGEMENT R. Narayanakumar Socio Economic Evaluation and Technology Transfer Division ICAR-Central Marine Fisheries Research Institute 23 Introduction Fishery resources are renewable natural resource but are liable to become extinct (as witnessed in many cases across the globe) if continuous and indiscriminate harvest is adopted Here the size of the stock (population) depends on the biological, economic and social considerations. Since fisheries resources are mostly coming under common property resources, its management becomes a complex issue (due to which a comprehensive management measure could not be exercised) and we have to resort to various management intervention options to ensure sustainable harvest as well as to maintain inter and intra generational equity. The management issue gains more significance in India wherein species diversity is very high and so the diversity among the fishing communities involved in fishing operations. In an open access regime like fishery, negative externalities are many, which implies that uncontrolled fishery will bound to end up in what is called tragedy of commons. (Grafton et.al, 2006). There are many fishery management indicators, or reference points, which are estimated based on the systematic landing data and stock assessment studies. These indicators form the basis for formulation of various management measures in the country. Among such reference points, maximum economic yield (MEY) is one. The concepts, estimation of MEY and its significance in fishery management are dealt with in the following sections. Sustainable Yield Before actually proceeding to MEY, it will be better to have an understanding on the concepts of sustainable yield for a better understanding. Fisheries are classified under renewable natural resources. However such resources are also liable to become extinct if the rate of harvest or exploitation is higher than the rate of regeneration or reproduction. Here the size of the stock (population) depends on the biological, economic and social considerations. 252 Summer School on Advanced Methods for Fish Stock Assessment and Fisheries Management

The sustainable yield in fishing commonly referred to as Maximum Sustainable Yield (MSY) is a biological phenomenon. MSY means that level of fish catch or yield that can be harvested from a given system in perpetuity without affecting the stock of the system (or the sea). In other words, a catch level is said to be sustainable whenever it equals the growth rate of the population since it can be maintained for ever. As long as the population size remains constant, the growth rate will remain constant as well. What is MEY? Maximum economic yield is that yield level, which coincides with the level of harvest or effort that maximized the sustainable net returns from fishing. A MEY harvest is desirable because it is the catch level that enables society to do the best it can with what nature has provided. (Grafton et al, 2006). Maximum Economic Yield (MEY) which includes the monetary terms of the effort and returns in sustainable yield formulation. In fisheries terms, maximum sustainable yield (MSY) is the largest average catch that can be captured from a stock under existing environmental conditions. Relating to MSY, the maximum economic yield (MEY) is the level of catch that provides the maximum net economic benefits or profits to society. MEY is a long-run equilibrium concept which refers to the level of output and the corresponding level of effort that maximize the expected economic profits in a fishery. In most cases, this scenario results in yields and effort levels that are less than at maximum sustainable yield (MSY) and in stock biomass levels greater than at MSY (Mardie 2002, Bromley,2009) Earlier only biological aspects were considered in fisheries management. But they were aimed at controlling fishing effort and they did not consider the economic or social aspects of fishing methods. The net income from fishing and the subsequent use of income for the livelihood of fishers is also of vital importance. Besides the cost and returns in fishing plays a significant role as incentives for engaging in fishing as an occupation. This thought gave way for the economics to be included in fisheries management. Summer School on Advanced Methods for Fish Stock Assessment and Fisheries Management 253

Economists have long argued that a fishery that maximizes its economic potential also usually will satisfy its conservation objectives (Walters 1993; Mardie 2002). This scenario is encapsulated in the concept of maximum economic yield (MEY), a long-run equilibrium concept that refers to the level of output and the corresponding level of effort that maximize the expected economic profits in a fishery. In most cases, this scenario results in yields and effort levels that are less than at maximum sustainable yield (MSY) and in stock biomass levels greater than at MSY (Mardie 2002, Bromley,2009). Lower levels of fishing effort also generally result in fewer adverse environmental impacts. Developed initially in the context of single-species fisheries (Walters, 1993), MEY was extended to multispecies fisheries under the assumption that the species are caught in fixed proportions. The optimal catch and biomass for any single species in a multispecies fishery may be greater or less than at MSY (Bromley, 2009). When the relationship between effort and money are measured, it was observed that when stock is low, effort must be high. Total revenue (TR) = Price (P) Catch (H) TC = Unit cost (c) Effort Rent = TR TC The rent is maximized at the point E*.Please note that here, MEY is left of MSY Optimal harvest (H*) is less than the MSY harvest But rent is larger than at MSY The point E* is that effort level at which the MEY occurs. At this point of effort only the difference between the total revenue from fishing and total cost of fishing is the maximum. This difference is also referred to as resource rent. 254 Summer School on Advanced Methods for Fish Stock Assessment and Fisheries Management

The marginal analysis can show that the MEY occurs at the point where MC =MR. It is observed that for marginal unit of effort, marginal rent is = 0 and average rent >1. Dixon concludes that the Goal of traditional fisheries management: achieve MSY. However the economists aim for MEY in contrast to MSY. AT MEY, compared to MSY, the fish catch is lower, fishing profit is higher, fishing effort is lower and the fish stock is higher. Thus the author concludes that MEY is where more fish is conserved. (Dixon, 2005) Steps in estimation of MEY Where, p = a -by....(1) p is the price per unit weight of fish y is the annual yield The average price per unit weight of fish (p) is generally a monotonically decreasing function of annual yield (y) The profit is obtained as a difference between total revenue (TR) and total cost (TC), i.e., Where Π = TR TC = (p-c)y... (2) c is the cost of harvesting one unit weight of fish. From this, a cost function will be fit from the data collected MEY = (a c) / 2b....(3) f mey = [a +/- (a 2 4 b MEY)] 1/2 / 2b (4) where, a = intercept; b, c =regression coefficients From f mey, the optimum fleet size is obtained by dividing b by the average annual fishing days. Based on this the excess capacity and thus the capital investment (over and above the optimum fleet size) can be worked out Summer School on Advanced Methods for Fish Stock Assessment and Fisheries Management 255

Factors Affecting MEY While estimating the MEY, three assumptions have been made such as zero discount rate; cost of fishing is a simple linear function of stock size; fishing costs rise proportionately with effort The cost of fishing is an important component that decides the MEY. Generally the cost of fishing increases with a decrease in stock size at an increasing rate. This is the characteristics of the fishing practice. Under such a situation, it will be desirable to have a catch and effort level further to the left of the bionomic equilibrium If the discount rate is very high or large, the MEY will correspond to a bionomic equilibrium (Clark, 1990), because it will be profitable to harvest the stock today itself if the loss of future net returns are very heavily discounted. Maximizing economic viability of fisheries is compatible with economic sustainability of the fisheries. Estimation of MEY becomes complicated due to biological interactions; apportioning of the cost of fishing; value of target versus by catches and splitting the efforts and related aspects; lack of complete biological data to calculate the stock-recruitment relationship; inability to accurately measure the actual catch and effort of fishers and the current size of the fish stock; price of fish and the precise cost of fishing. A fall in fish price or an increase in cost of fishing will lead to lower harvest with a less fishing effort and a larger stock size in order to maximize the economic profits (Grafton et.al. 2006) Importance of MEY Fisheries Management MEY is a good target reference point for fisheries management despite the assumptions made. MEY ensures that the stock levels in many fisheries are larger than those associated with the traditional MSY target. MEY also ensures that the major inputs like fuel and labour are optimally utilized to maximize the profit. MEY helps to estimate the excess fishing capacity in the sector, which provides one of the strong bases for recommending optimum fleet size. If the resources are used beyond the MEY target, it will result in excess fishing capacity, lower returns and thus lower profits. Hence it pays rich dividend to follow the MEY as an important component for aiming at a sustainable fishery. Conclusion MEY acts an important link between the biological and economic implications of fisheries management. Taking cue from tragedy of commons that unmanaged natural resources are depleted completely and some sort of regulation measures are need to ensure sustainable utilization. In case of fisheries the economics of fishing operations (cost and returns) determine not only the profitability of the profession but also the driving force for remaining in the sector. In this context, the MEY which incorporates the costs of fishing the revenue earned into the sustainable yield models, provide an acceptable method for formulating fishery management plants. As reported by a few studies, the biological reference point (MSY) and the economic reference point (MEY) are always compliments to each other and they should be employed in formulation of any fishery management policies in the country. 256 Summer School on Advanced Methods for Fish Stock Assessment and Fisheries Management

Suggested Reading Bromley, D. W., 2009. Abdicating responsibility: The Deceits of Fisheries policy. Fisheries 34: 280 291. Clarke, C.W., 1990. Mathematical bioeconomics: the Optimal Management of Renewable Resources, John Wiley & Sons, New York. Devaraj, M. and Smita, P. 1988. Economic performance of mechanised trawlers in the State of Kerala, India. Fisheries Research, 6 (3): 271-286. FAO Fishing Technology Service, 1996. FAO Technical Guidelines for Responsible Fisheries, No.1, Rome, FAO, 26pp Fox, W. W. Jr., 1970. An Exponential Surplus-Yield Model for Optimizing Exploited Fish Populations. Transactions of the American Fisheries Society, 99: 80-88. Gordon, H. Scott, 1954. The Economic Theory of a Common Property Resource. Journal of Political Economy, 62:124-142 Grafton, R. Q., James Kirekly, Toom Kompas and Dale Squires, 2006. Economics of Fisheries Management. Ashgate Publishing Company, England, p.160 Hilborn R. W., 2007 Economics of overexploitation revisited. Science 318:1601 John A. D., 2005. Fisheries and Aquatic Resources. Caspian EVE 2005/UNDP and WBI Kompas T., 2009. Comment on Abdicating responsibility: The Deceits of Fisheries policy. Fisheries 34:292 294. Mardle S, et al., 2002. Objectives of fisheries management: Case studies from the UK, France, Spain and Denmark. Mar Policy 26:415 428 Schaefer, M., 1957. Some Considerations of Population Dynamics and Economics in relation to the Management of the Commercial Marine Fisheries. Journal of the Fisheries Research Board of Canada,14: 69-681. Townsend, R. E., 1990. Entry restrictions in the Fishery: A Survey of the Evidence, Land Economics, 66:359-378 Walters C., 1993. Uncertainty, resource exploitation, and conservation: Lessons from history. Science 260: 17 36. Wilen, J., 1979. Fishermen Behaviour and the Design of Efficient Fisheries Regulation Programmes. Journal of Fisheries Research Board of Canada, 36: 855-858. Worm B, et al., 2009. Rebuilding global fisheries. Science 325:578 585. Summer School on Advanced Methods for Fish Stock Assessment and Fisheries Management 257