Could Welfare Optimality be Achieved with Extensive Data Information?

Similar documents
Economics, fisheries and responsible fisheries management

MAXIMUM ECONOMIC YIELD AND ITS IMPORTANCE IN FISHERIES MANAGEMENT

The Potential Economic Impact on Selected Fishing Fleet Segments of TACs Proposed by ACFM for 2004 (EIAA-model calculations)

Management of the North Sea flatfish fishery: exploring alternative ITQ systems IIFET 2014, Brisbane, July 9 th 2014 K. G. Hamon, H. Bartelings, F.

BSAC recommendations for the fishery in the Baltic Sea in 2018

Fully Documented Fisheries

The landings obligation in view of different management regimes

Annual Report on fishing fleet capacity Denmark. Section A. 23 May 2017

Københavns Universitet. Linking effort and fishing mortality in a mixed fisheries model Thøgersen, Thomas Talund; Hoff, Ayoe; Frost, Hans Staby

Advice June Sole in Division IIIa and Subdivisions (Skagerrak, Kattegat, and the Belts)

Proposal for a COUNCIL REGULATION

6.3.8 Advice May 2014 Version 2, ECOREGION North Sea STOCK Herring in Division IIIa and Subdivisions (western Baltic spring spawners)

6.4 Stock summaries Advice June 2012

Herring (Clupea harengus) in subdivisions 20 24, spring spawners (Skagerrak, Kattegat, and western Baltic)

Sandeel (Ammodytes spp.) in Divisions IIIa, IVa, and IVb, SA 3 (Skagerrak and Kattegat, North and Central North Sea)

Comment on What Restoration Schemes Can Do. Or, Getting It Right Without Fisheries Transferable Quotas

Cod (Gadus morhua) in subdivisions 24 32, eastern Baltic stock (eastern Baltic Sea) *

From right-based catch shares to benthic impacts

Using Fishermen s Expertise to Improve Fisheries Management

How illegal discarding. failing EU fisheries. and citizens. How illegal discarding in. fisheries and citizens. Executive summary

MAXIMUM ECONOMIC YIELD AND RESOURCE ALLOCATION IN THE SPINY LOBSTER INDUSTRY* Joel S. Williams and Fred J. Prochaska

DK-E A EUROPEAN COMMISSION DIRECTORATE-GENERAL FOR MARITIME AFFAIRS AND FISHERIES MISSION REPORT. Denmark. Dates: from 10/03/15 to 11/03/15

STECF work on the Landing Obligation. Advising on: The biggest challenge? The biggest puzzle? The biggest risk?

AGEC 604 Natural Resource Economics

Plaice (Pleuronectes platessa) in Subarea 4 (North Sea) and Subdivision 20 (Skagerrak)

5.16 NETHERLANDS. Short description of the national fleet. Fleet capacity. Fleet structure. Employment. Effort. Production

Fishing opportunities for 2018 under the Common Fisheries Policy

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION. Fishing Opportunities for 2009 Policy Statement from the European Commission

Please note: The present advice replaces the advice given in June 2017 for catches in 2018.

4.9 92,000. Healthy fisheries are good for business How better management of European fisheries will create jobs and improve the economy

Sprat (Sprattus sprattus) in subdivisions (Baltic Sea)

Sprat (Sprattus sprattus) in Division 3.a (Skagerrak and Kattegat)

Why has the cod stock recovered in the North Sea?

THE NORWEGIAN STRUCTURAL POLICY - MAINTAINING PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH WITH A LIMITED NATURAL RESOURCE.

Saithe (Pollachius virens) in subareas 4 and 6, and in Division 3.a (North Sea, Rockall and West of Scotland, Skagerrak and Kattegat)

Sustainable Fisheries for Future Generations The Fisheries White Paper

Norway lobster (Nephrops norvegicus) in Division 4.a, Functional Unit 7 (northern North Sea, Fladen Ground)

Boarfish (Capros aper) in subareas 6 8 (Celtic Seas, English Channel, and Bay of Biscay)

Sandeel (Ammodytes spp.) in Divisions 3a, 4a, and 4b, SA 3 (Skagerrak and Kattegat, North and Central North Sea)

EU request on management areas for sandeel in the North Sea

Norway lobster (Nephrops norvegicus) in Division 4.b, Functional Unit 6 (central North Sea, Farn Deeps)

Rent generation and dissipation in the Western Central Pacific tuna fishery. Michael Harte. July 2016

Norway lobster (Nephrops norvegicus) in Division 4.b, Functional Unit 6 (central North Sea, Farn Deeps)

Evaluation of fisheries dependent information in European waters 5-9 September 2016, Gavirate

Annex 7: Request on management areas for sandeel in the North Sea

By-Catch and Discard Management: The Key to Achieving Responsible and Sustainable Fisheries in Europe

Plaice (Pleuronectes platessa) in Subarea 4 (North Sea) and Subdivision 20 (Skagerrak)

Plaice (Pleuronectes platessa) in Division 7.e (western English Channel)

Advice June 2014

Council of the European Union Brussels, 23 November 2016 (OR. en)

Herring (Clupea harengus) in subdivisions and 32 (central Baltic Sea, excluding Gulf of Riga)

Best Practice Guidance for Assessing the Financial Performance of Fishing Gear: Industry-led gear trials

Angling Trust Save Our Sea Bass Bass Position Statement 2018

Danish Pelagic and Demersal Individual Transferable Quota Programs

Norway lobster (Nephrops norvegicus) in Division 4.a, Functional Unit 10 (northern North Sea, Noup)

COUNCIL REGULATION (EU)

Council CNL(16)21. Annual Progress Report on Actions Taken Under the Implementation Plan for the Calendar Year 2015

Norway lobster (Nephrops norvegicus) in Division 4.a, Functional Unit 32 (northern North Sea, Norway Deep)

(Non-legislative acts) REGULATIONS

COUNCIL REGULATION (EU)

establishing further emergency measures in 2017 and 2018 for small pelagic stocks in the Adriatic Sea (GSA 17 and GSA 18)

Herring (Clupea harengus) in subdivisions 20 24, spring spawners (Skagerrak, Kattegat, and western Baltic)

Advice June, revised September Herring in Division IIIa and Subdivisions (Western Baltic spring spawners)

9.4.5 Advice September Widely distributed and migratory stocks Herring in the Northeast Atlantic (Norwegian spring-spawning herring)

SEAFISH ECONOMIC ANALYSIS

Integrating different user groups into fishery management

Fish for the Future. Transferable Fishing Concessions The solution to overfishing or a problem in itself? S&D

Norway lobster (Nephrops norvegicus) in Division 3.a, functional units 3 and 4 (Skagerrak and Kattegat)

Roundnose grenadier (Coryphaenoides rupestris) in Division 3.a (Skagerrak and Kattegat)

The Plan covers an initial recovery phase as well as a long-term management phase and shall consist of the following elements.

Proposal for a COUNCIL REGULATION

ICES Advice on fishing opportunities, catch, and effort Celtic Seas and Greater North Sea ecoregions Published 30 June 2016

Fishing Capacity and Efficient Fleet Configuration for the Tuna Purse Seine Fishery in the Eastern Pacific Ocean: An Economic Approach

FLEET ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE DATASET

Advice June 2012

13196/16 AS/JGC/sr DGB 2A

Comments on the Green Paper for the reform of the Common Fisheries Policy

FISHERY BY-PRODUCT REPORT

3.4.3 Advice June Barents Sea and Norwegian Sea Cod in Subareas I and II (Norwegian coastal waters cod)

OR DUNGENESS CRAB FISHERY:

Plaice (Pleuronectes platessa) in subdivisions (Baltic Sea, excluding the Sound and Belt Seas)

Can a discard ban be good for fishers?

Haddock (Melanogrammus aeglefinus) in divisions 7.b k (southern Celtic Seas and English Channel)

A Note on the Stock Effect

(Non-legislative acts) REGULATIONS

Plaice (Pleuronectes platessa) in Subarea IV (North Sea) and Division IIIa (Skagerrak)

A New Fisheries Policy

COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION. Consultation on Fishing Opportunities for 2011

CHAPTER 12: FISHERIES

ICES Advice on fishing opportunities, catch, and effort Celtic Seas Ecoregion Published 30 June 2016

EU request to ICES on in-year advice on haddock (Melanogrammus aeglefinus) in Division 7.a (Irish Sea)

Potential Economic Repercussions of a Discards Ban in EU Fisheries

Implications of reducing Norway lobster (Nephrops norvegicus) minimum size (MLS/MCRS) in the Skagerrak and Kattegat area (IIIa).

Witch (Glyptocephalus cynoglossus) in Subarea 4 and divisions 3.a and 7.d (North Sea, Skagerrak and Kattegat, eastern English Channel)

Draft Discussion Document. May 27, 2016

ICES advice on fishing opportunities

2.3.1 Advice May Capelin in Subareas V and XIV and Division IIa west of 5 W (Iceland East Greenland Jan Mayen area).

NASCO Guidelines for the Management of Salmon Fisheries

MOVING TO RIGHTS BASED MANAGEMENT: GREEN-LIPPED MUSSEL CASE STUDY. Martin Workman, Ministry of Fisheries, New Zealand,

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES. Proposal for a COUNCIL REGULATION

Transcription:

Marine Resource Economics, Volume 18, pp. 275 286 0738-1360/00 $3.00 +.00 Printed in the U.S.A. All rights reserved Copyright 2003 Marine Resources Foundation Could Welfare Optimality be Achieved with Extensive Data Information? HANS FROST Danish Research Institute of Food Economics FRANK JENSEN University of Southern Denmark Abstract This paper examines whether the Danish management system achieves welfare maximisation. For cod in the North Sea, Skagerrak, and Kattegat, rations are used. It is shown that rations raise substantial information requirements and that the existing allocation of rations is inoptimal. In addition, a linear programming model is used to show that there is considerable overcapacity in the Danish trawler fleet in the Baltic Sea. Danish fisheries managers have access to an extensive data set, and with the available information it would be possible to secure a welfare optimum. Key words Fisheries management, EU fisheries policy, welfare optimality, extensive data information, economic incentives, enforcement, and linear programming. JEL Classification Codes Q21, Q22, K42, C61. Introduction The EU fisheries are regulated through a common fisheries policy. This policy was agreed upon in 1982 and consists of a market policy, a structural policy, an external policy, a control policy, and a conservation policy. In the market policy, a system of market supports is established (Holden 1996), while the purpose of the structural policy is to seek to coordinate development in fishing capacity and stock abundance (Lynge-Jensen 2000). An important part of the structural policy is the Multi-Annual Guidance Programmes (MAGP), which set objectives for development in fishing capacity. The purpose of the external policy is to negotiate fishing agreements with third countries (Holden 1996), while the intentions of the control policy are to ensure compliance with the regulations (Lynge-Jensen 2000). An important aspect of the control policy is that responsibility for control is placed at Member State level. The conservation policy consists of Total Allowable Catch (TAC) policy and various technical conservation measures such as gear restrictions, closed areas, etc. (Karagiannakos 1995). In the TAC policy, a total quota for each species is determined every year. These quotas are then allocated to the Member States of the EU based on their historic shares of the landings of each species (named relative stability). It is then up to the Hans Frost is a senior economic adviser at the Danish Research Institute of Food Economics, Rolighedsvej 25, DK-1958 Frederiksberg C (Copenhagen), Denmark, email: hf@foi.dk. Frank Jensen is an assistant professor at the University of Southern Denmark, Niels Bohrs Vej 9, DK-6700 Esbjerg Denmark, email: fje@sam.sdu.dk. 275

276 Frost and Jensen Member States to decide which fishermen are going to harvest the quota. In Denmark, rations or annual allocations are used to distribute the EU-determined quota to fishermen. A ration is an individual, non-transferable quota on short time intervals, while an annual allocation is a yearly, non-transferable quota. However, the EU and the Danish fisheries policy face four main problems. First, the fish stocks suffer from serious overexploitation (Anon. 2000). From an economics standpoint, this result is not surprising because it is the predicted outcome under open access (Warming 1911) and regulated open access (Homans and Wilen 1997). Second, the scientific recommendation is, roughly speaking, based on a single-species assumption, while in reality the fisheries are multi-species. Therefore, the economic recommendations about fisheries policy ought to depart from the economic theory of joint production (Andersen 1979). Third, there is excess fishing capacity, which is difficult to estimate empirically. Fourth, the fish stocks are shared among several countries and, therefore, economic recommendations should depart from game theory. The purpose of this paper is to highlight to what extent the Danish management system achieves welfare maximisation. In order to answer this question, attention is restricted to a short-run analysis mainly because of the lack of understanding of fish stock development (Anon. 2000). It is argued that a ration fishery raises substantial information requirements and that the existing ration allocation is inoptimal. Furthermore, results of a linear programming model conclude that there are noncompliance incentives with the regulation and that substantial overcapacity exists. For simplicity, the paper focuses on fleet segments for which cod constitutes the most important species in the catch composition. In terms of fisheries management, Denmark is characterised by the availability of comprehensive data information; e.g. data on trip-level vessel landings and information about individual vessel costs (Anon. 1999). With this information it would, by application of appropriate management measures, be possible to secure optimal capacity and ration allocation. Because the necessary information is already collected, there are no additional data collection costs associated with improved application of this information with respect to welfare improvements. The paper is organised as follows. The next section describes the Danish management system, while the welfare properties of the ration fishery are discussed after that. The issue of overcapacity in the Danish fishery is then highlighted, followed by the conclusion. Legal Rules for Fishing Cod in the North Sea A set of legal rules forms a basis for the actions taken by fishermen. The legal basis for exploitation of all stocks is rather complex. Therefore, the management of the cod fishery has been selected, because cod is the most important species for human consumption in Denmark. 1 Cod is managed in four areas: the North Sea, Skagerrak, Kattegat, and the Baltic Sea. In the first three areas, a ration fishery is used as the management measure. A ration can be defined as an allocation of a yearly quota over short time periods and according to vessel length. The allocation of the yearly quota to fishermen is per- 1 Cod constituted between 22% and 28% of total landings value over the last five years (Anon. 1999). Cod is targeted in mixed species fisheries in which gill netters and small demersal trawlers (below 50 GT) are the most important type of vessels, with cod constituting around 60% of the total landings value for the gill netters and around 33% for the trawlers.

Welfare Optimality and Extensive Data Information 277 formed in three steps. First, the quota is distributed in intervals over the year taking seasonal variations into account. In the North Sea and Skagerrak, the yearly quota is distributed evenly over the year, while the first months receive a larger share of the annual quota in Kattegat and the Baltic Sea. Second, the seasonal quota is allocated to fishermen according vessel length. 2 Third, an adjustment procedure is used to change the initial allocation according to benchmarks which are the quotas fixed for each time interval over the year and the catch of each vessel relative to the allocated individual rations. There is no restriction on the number of vessels that may participate in the cod fishery. 3 The ration periods vary from one week to two months, which makes it possible for the manager to change the ration more or less frequently relative to development in landings. With the aim of building further flexibility into the management system, the ration in each sub-period may be exceeded up to 20%. The excess catch in one ration period is then deducted from the next period s ration. However, the ration of the last period in a year cannot be exceeded, because transfers to the next year are not allowed. Furthermore, transfers of quantities that have not been caught within the relevant ration period are not possible. The rations are calculated by the Fisheries Directorate based on the last year s average catch rates in the different vessel categories and adjusted for changes in the quota of the current year relative to last year. In figure 1, vessel length is plotted against the rations for the North Sea and Skagerrak. Medium-sized vessels receive a larger share of the quota compared to other vessel sizes, which is determined by the catch composition of the average vessel in each length group. Because cod is relatively more important in the Baltic Sea compared to other waters, the management system in the Baltic Sea is different from the management system in the other areas. It is also more detailed with the flexibility to make frequent adjustments in allocations based on each vessel s performance. First, a license is required for fishing cod. However, all vessels that apply are granted a license. Once a license is granted, the vessel must not fish outside the Baltic Sea. With a license two choices exist: ration fishery and annual, individual non-transferable quotas. The main difference between the two systems is the fishermen s planning period. While annual allocations make it certain how much could be caught and when, rations may change over time. Vessels that fished two years before the actual year in which annual allocations are granted are allowed to catch the amount caught in the best of the two years plus an additional 25%. However, the annual allocation for those vessels must not exceed a predetermined allocation, which increases with vessel size and applies to all vessels. If a vessel has caught at least 80% of its initial allocation before mid-june, it is granted an additional amount. This is not automatic, the vessel owner has to apply for the extra amount. On the other hand, a reduction in the next year s annual allocation will occur if the vessel does not catch the allocated annual quantity. The vessel may also give notice of exit from the fishery for one or several months. This is costly because the annual allocation is then reduced by 10% per month. For June, July, and August, which is the low season, notice of exit can only be given for all three months with a 10% reduction in the vessel s total annual allocation. If the vessel has caught less than 50% of the annual allocation by mid June, it is forced to return the difference between the catch and 50% of the annual allocation. The same applies by mid-october, when the rate is 80%. 2 The allocation scheme is published in the law. 3 Remark that a license system is applied, and all that apply for a license receive it.

278 Frost and Jensen Figure 1. Actual Ration Allocation Associated with this management system is a system of enforcement, control, prosecution, and punishment. However, this is a slow, indirect system. The time lag is long, and the whole procedure is resource intensive. The Fisheries Directorate is responsible for monitoring noncompliance activities by the fishermen. According to a catalogue developed by the Directorate, a decision is reached regarding which violations should be subject to administrative settlement and which should be subject to public prosecution and handed over to the police. The police have the power to institute prosecution and bring fishermen to trial. The Danish management system makes heavy use of a penalty system to ensure compliance with the regulations. This system is described in the Directorate s catalogue, which is known by the fishermen although they may not know the penalty rates by heart. A fine and confiscation of the value of the excess landings minus the landing cost compose the total penalty to the fishermen. The purpose of the next two sections is to provide an indication of whether or not this rather detailed management system achieves welfare maximisation. Short-run Analysis of Rations and Annual Allocations A regulatory model from Clark (1990) is used to highlight whether the ration fishery achieves welfare maximisation. Perfect information is assumed, and a ration fishery with only two ration periods, 1 and 2, is considered for simplicity. Let y 1i and y 2i denote catches in period 1 and 2 for fisherman i, and E 1i and E 2i denote the effort in the two periods for fisherman i. The fish stock is labelled x. The possibility of exceeding the ration by 20% is ignored, and it is assumed that the accessibility of the fish differs for the two periods because of seasonal variations. Call the accessibility coefficient for period 1 q 1 (x), and the accessibility coefficient for period 2 q 2 (x). The cost functions are C 1i (E 1i ) and C 2i (E 2i ). Because y 1i = q 1 (x)e 1i, the ration restriction corresponds to q 1 (x)e 1i Q 1i, where Q 1i is the ration for period 1. It is also assumed

Welfare Optimality and Extensive Data Information 279 that the fishermen ignore any resource conservation measures. Therefore, if p is the price of fish, the maximisation problem for fisherman i may be written as: Max[ pq 1 (x)e 1i c 1i (E 1i ) + pq 2 (x)e 2 i c 2i (E 2i )] (1) s.t. q 1 (x )E 1i Q 1i (2) q 2 (x )E 21i Q 2i. (3) For periods 1 and 2, there are several possibilities depending on whether the ration restrictions are binding. Assume first that equations (2) and (3) are binding. In this case, the first-order condition for period 1 is: (p λ 1i )q 1 (x) = c 1i E 1i, (4) where λ 1i is a Lagrange multiplier for period 1 for fisherman i. Optimality requires that λ 1i = λ 2i = λ 1j = λ 2j = µ for all j i, where µ is the social user cost of the fish stock. In other words, the ration restriction shadow prices must be identical between vessels and periods. The information requirements of this system are enormous, and as currently managed, optimality in the ration fishery will not be reached. This point is explained further in figure 2. Assume next that the ration restriction is nonbinding. In this case, the first-order condition for period 1 is: pq 1 (x ) = c 1i E 1i. (5) This corresponds to the open-access condition, and under open-access it is well known that λ 1i 0. Therefore, rations have no effect on instantaneous effort. If the problem is slightly reformulated, it is possible to address a case of annual allocations that is an alternative option to rations for the Baltic Sea cod fishery. Recall that the period 2 allocations are reduced when catches in period 1 are less than 80% of the annual allocation, Q 1i. The restriction that applies in this case is: q 2 (x)e 2i q 1 (x)e 1i if q 1 (x) 0.8Q 1i. (6) Because of changes in the accessibility coefficients due to seasonal variations, q 1 (x) and q 2 (x) can be different between periods. In the case where q 1 (x) q 2 (x), equation (6) is not binding. If q 1 (x) < q 2 (x), the restriction can be binding. With equation (6) binding, the first-order condition is: (p + λ 2i )q 1 (x) = c 1i E 1i. (7) Equation (7) shows that fishermen face an opportunity cost for fishing less than 80% of the annual allocation in period 1. This cost is the value of the loss of fishing op-

280 Frost and Jensen Figure 2. Optimal Ration Allocation portunity in period 2. To avoid this cost, fishermen could choose to harvest at least 80% of the annual allocation. In defence of the annual allocation system, the 80% exists because the vessels are heterogeneous, and the managers realise that they do not have perfect information. If some vessels are not willing or able to catch at least 80% of the annual allocation, it is taken from them and returned to the manager to avoid grey trade. Furthermore, the 80% rule exists in order to provide the manager with correct information with respect to improved reallocation. It should also be mentioned that fishermen who have caught 80% of their allocation for the current year before mid- June can apply for more. 4 This makes the annual allocation system flexible. In theory, the optimal allocation of rations secures that the marginal welfare is equal between vessels and periods. The information requirements of this allocation are rather comprehensive. With available account statistics, an approximation for the true allocation to vessel categories can be: Annual ration to segment 1 = TR VC 1 1, (8) TR i VC i where TR is total revenue and VC is variable costs. In order to highlight the inefficiency of the existing allocation, such an allocation has been performed for cod. The results are summarised in figure 2. The calculations are based on the assumptions that the vessels are homogeneous within the vessel categories and that they can fish in all waters. In practise, these assumptions are not fulfilled. Note also that the rations in figure 2 apply to all vessels. Comparing figures 1 and 2, it is clear that the large vessels ought to receive a larger share of the quota. However, with cost information at the vessel level, it would be 4 The rate and date may vary from year to year.

Welfare Optimality and Extensive Data Information 281 possible to estimate an individual cost function. Therefore, an optimal allocation of rations, where the marginal profit is equal between vessels and time periods, can be ensured. It is important to note that the Danish control policy can be interpreted as a tax system because the penalties are known ex ante. 5 The problem with implementing a tax system is that not only is it necessary to tie the tax to a subject (in fisheries, the landings of a species), but it is also necessary to determine who is to be charged. For example, when issuing traffic fines for speeding, it is not sufficient to know just the license plate. The identity of the driver must also be established. This point can be seen from the following court trial for two pairs of trawlers that have exceeded their individual quota allocation. The case is complicated by the realistic legal circumstance that one of the vessels was fishing with two different skippers one of them being the owner. The case is shown in table 1. Both vessels recorded the excess landings correctly in the logbook. The skipper explained to the court that it was his expectation that the allocation (individual quota) could be increased towards the end of the year, or alternatively, that the excess volume would be deducted from the next year s allocation. That may explain the correct recording in the logbooks. However, the court emphasised that the vessel did not have, at the time of violation, the necessary individual quota. The total penalty relative to the total revenue is 26.6% if the owner of vessel #2 also pays for a hired skipper. If the fine (item 1) is put relative to the profit after crew remuneration and depreciation, but before interest, the fine is about 15% of the profit. The profit relative to the gross revenue for this vessel category is about 22% (Anon. 1999). It should be noted that the fine would have been three times higher if the excess landings had not been recorded in the logbooks. It is also worth noting that the fine is calculated from the gross revenue less landing costs, but before crew wages. This implies that the confiscation of excess landings is a burden for the owner if he cannot make the crew return their salaries. On the other hand, the penalty signals that the crew is also responsible for the violation, which is entailed by the crew share system applied in the Danish fishery. This makes the Danish enforcement system a tax system that is designed to ensure compliance with the quota. Table 1 Results from Studying a Penalty Case, Euro and kg Vessel #1 Vessel #2 Skipper Skipper #1 Skipper #2 Total 1. Licence allocation (kg) 672,000 2. License allocation (Euro) 297,349 297,349 594,698 3. Landings (kg) 930,112 4. Landings (Euro) 411,559 411,559 823,119 5. Excess landings (kg) 129,056 33,752 95,304 823,119 6. Excess landings (Euro) 114,210 29,869 84,341 258,112 7. Landings costs (Euro) 228,421 8. Net revenue (Euro) 99,363 99,363 29,695 9. Fine 10% (Euro) 9,933 2,859 7,034 198,726 10.Total penalty (Euro) 109,292 102,218 19,826 11.Item 10/Item 4 (%) 26.6 24.8 5 Harford (1984) also interprets a penalty as a tax.

282 Frost and Jensen In the next section, the incentive for noncompliance is highlighted. From the point of view of welfare economics, it is shown that the quotas and capacity do not match each other and that there is excess capacity in the Danish fishery. Incentives for Noncompliance In systems where constraints are imposed, hidden values are created (Dantzig 1963). Those shadow prices reflect that the fishery is not allowed to reach an equilibrium where marginal revenue is equal to marginal costs. If a fishery is managed by limiting the number of fishing days to a lower level than where revenues equal costs of a marginal day, a shadow value showing the contribution to profit of a marginal day is generated. The fishery considered for further analysis is the Baltic Sea trawl fishery. The model contains three trawler segments (A, B, C) and five species groups. These species groups include all important species found in the Baltic Sea. Apart from trawlers that include both demersal and pelagic gear, the fishery is carried out by gill netters that catch about 25% of the cod by volume but only about 7% of the total landings from the Baltic Sea. Gill netters are not included because the catch per day information required for the analysis is more uncertain relative to that for trawlers. The catch composition of the fleet segments is made up of these species in different compositions. The average crew, including the skipper, is two in segment A, three in segment B, and four in segment C. The model maximises the remuneration to the crew including the skipper/owner and the net profit. This is chosen because a collective decision between skipper and crew is assumed if noncompliance with restrictions is going to be accomplished successfully. The economic characteristics of the three fleet segments are displayed in table 2. Revenue and costs are shown for the average vessel, and costs are distributed (dependent) on the number of fishing days (C(NOFD)), landings in volume (C(LAND)), landings in value (C(VLAND)), and fixed costs. Costs are extracted annually from the cost and earnings statistics and recalculated to unit costs (per fishing day, per kg landed, and per unit value landed). Crew wages are dependent on revenue from the landings, and the percentage share is calculated based on the annual figures. The objective of the fisherman is to maximise the profit of his own vessel and crew, therefore, share the interest of the skipper/owner. The profit function for a vessel in fleet segment k is: 6 Maxπ k = ( p tik q tik NOFD tk cd k NOFD tk cv k p tik q tik NOFD tk cl k q tik NOFD tk cf k ), (9) where: ti NOFD is the number of fishing days per time period (t) and vessel segment (k); NOFD is the choice variable and is considered a proxy for effort; p is the price for species i; q tik is the catch per day in quarter t of species i in vessel segment k; cd k is the cost per day at sea for fleet segment k; cv k is the landing value cost for fleet segment k; cl k is the landing volume cost for fleet segment k; cf k is the fixed cost per vessel for fleet segment k. 6 A similar model is used in Frost and Andersen (2001).

Welfare Optimality and Extensive Data Information 283 Table 2 Economic Characteristics of Danish Trawlers Fishing in the Baltic Sea Fleet Segments A (12 14 m) B (14 24 m) C (> 24 m) Euro Revenue 168,501 431,335 637,762 C(NOFD) 21,879 58,773 79,737 C(LAND) 988 4,964 6,203 C(VLAND ) 17,149 40,906 64,789 C(WAGES) 76,149 197,726 289,627 Fixed Costs 19,172 67,599 179,553 Profit 109,312 259,093 307,480 The manager s objective is to maximise rent for the entire fishing ground. The objective function, therefore, includes the number of vessels, V. 7 There are no effects of fish stock change in the objective function: Max Π = (p tik q tik NOFD tk cd k NOFD tk (10) tik cv k p tik q tik NOFD tk cl k q tik NOFD tk cf k )V k. The short-time allocated rations and annual individual non-transferable allocations are recorded in the database of the Fisheries Directorate for each vessel, and ideally they ought to be applied in the model. To use that amount of data would require substantial computer and software capacity. Therefore, the individual vessel allocations are, for our purposes, substituted with a limited number of fishing days which is sufficient to demonstrate the fundamental issues of the analysis, such as shadow prices and effort reallocation. In the fishery under examination, limitation of the rations becomes binding before the maximum number of fishing days. Therefore, the maximum number of fishing days limit is reduced to reflect the ration limitations for each fleet segment. In a system where the number of fishing days is restricted, the constraints differ for the fisherman and the manager. The fisherman faces a limited number of fishing days per time period, while the manager faces a quota restriction. In this model, which is a short-run model, the time period is quarterly and the restriction of the fisherman can be expressed as: NOFD tk G tk, (11) where G can be defined as the physical maximum number of days available to the vessel. Restrictions imposed by the manager are designed to control the amount of capital: 7 The number of vessels is used as a proxy for capacity, which multiplied by the number of fishing days approximates fishing effort.

284 Frost and Jensen V k U k, (12) where U is the maximum number of vessels in a segment. Furthermore, contribution to the margin in the short run and the profit in the long run has to be larger than zero. Otherwise, the fisherman will exit. This implies that: π, Π 0. (13) The restriction of the manager is that the quotas must not be exceeded. This restriction can be formulated as: q tik NOFD tk V k Q i, (14) tk where Q is the quota restriction for each species. The incentives for noncompliance are calculated by using an optimization model (linear programming) applied to catch, costs, and earnings data for the Baltic Sea in 1997. The selected fleet is the trawler fleet that is dominant in the Baltic Sea. Because the model is linear in days at sea, the fishermen will push days at sea to the physical limit, given the limitations of other inputs, which are assumed that the manager can control. The number of fishing days is limited to 55 for fleet segment A and 60 for fleet segment B in all quarters. Vessels in fleet segment C do not fish in the Baltic Sea between May and October. Therefore, the number of fishing days is fixed at a low level in the second quarter and set to zero in the third quarter for fleet segment C. The landings of cod and fish for reduction constitute the highest part of the total landings for fleet segment A, while the highest part of the total landings is reduction and herring in fleet segment C. However, there is considerable variation in the landing of species between quarters. The total landings have to be within the agreed upon quotas. For cod, fish for reduction, and herring the quotas are totally used, while the quotas are not used for plaice and other species. With respect to landings per day (productivity) measured in cod, fleet segment B has the highest productivity each year. Therefore, this fleet segment could claim the highest number of fishing days. There is also considerable variation in the productivity between quarters and fleet segments in these quarters. Some results of the model are shown in table 3. From table 3 it is seen that the optimal number of vessels should be 16, 192, and 5, respectively. The number of vessels shown in this table is not the actual number of vessels that were fishing in 1997 but the number that, given conditions in 1997, was the optimal composition with respect to maximising profit for the entire fishery. This number is calculated by use of a non-linear programming model. The model produces a series of shadow prices of an extra fishing day from the point of view of the fisherman and society, respectively. These shadow prices are also included in table 3. The solution for the fishermen is limited by the number of fishing days that is fixed by the manager for each vessel in each fleet segment. If, for example, a type C vessel could employ one more day in the second quarter, he would add Euro 2.79 thousands. If the same vessels employ one extra fishing day in the third quarter, no contribution would be obtained because this vessel type would either not catch anything or the opportunity costs would be too high. Assuming profit maximising behaviour, it is obvious that the fisherman would try to expand his fishery. Therefore, noncompliance behaviour is a natural consequence of the results shown in table 3. A further implication of the shadow prices calculated for the fishermen is that they show considerable overcapacity in the fishery. This can be concluded because the shadow prices are positive.

Welfare Optimality and Extensive Data Information 285 Table 3 Optimal Number of Vessels and Shadow Prices for Fishing Days for Fishermen and Managers Fishermen Society A 16 Optimal Number B 191 of Vessels C 5 Marginal Remuneration Euro Marginal Remuneration Euro 1. Quarter A 1,011 1,115 1. Quarter B 1,555-6,384 1. Quarter C 2,459 3,785 2. Quarter A 563 1,164 2. Quarter B 1,502 18,414 2. Quarter C 2,793 9,015 3. Quarter A 340 543 3. Quarter B 1,141 70,268 3. Quarter C 0 0 4. Quarter A 417 2,807 4. Quarter B 1,232 127,186 4. Quarter C 3,858 7,426 If the problem is considered from the manager s point of view, the results are different because of the quota restriction. The remuneration to labour from an extra fishing day differs from that of the fisherman because, given the restrictions, the marginal vessel in any segment would only lead to a reduction in other segments. The manager would have no incentive to increase the number of vessels. Table 3 illustrates that fleet segment B in the fourth quarter yields Euro 127.2 thousands subject to the quota restriction. This is Euro 0.66 thousands per vessel, while the individual vessel owner thinks he would contribute Euro 1.23 thousands. The analysis above shows that with available information, it is possible to calculate optimal capacity (optimal number of vessels). With optimal capacity, the shadow price on fishing days for the manager would be zero. Thus, welfare improvements could be ensured with available information. Conclusion This paper analyzes whether the Danish management system achieves welfare maximisation. In Denmark, rations and/or annual allocations are used as a management system. Based on a model from Clark (1990), it is shown that ration fishery raises substantial information requirements. Furthermore, it is shown that the existing allocation of rations is inoptimal. For cod in the Baltic Sea, fishermen can choose between annual allocations and rations. For annual allocations, a rule is that next year s allocation is reduced if this year s harvest is less than 80% of the annual

286 Frost and Jensen allocation. It is also shown that the 80% rule creates an opportunity cost. This cost is the value of lost fishing opportunity in the next year. The paper also includes a small linear/non-linear programming model in order to highlight the excess capacity issue in the Danish fleet. In the model, the fisherman maximises the profit plus the remuneration to crew, while the manager maximises the welfare of the whole fleet. The fisherman and the manager face different restrictions. The fisherman is restricted by the number of fishing days, while the quotas restrict the manager. The results of the programming model are that there are considerable incentives to noncompliance with the regulations, because there is a positive shadow price of the fishing day restriction. The implication of this is that there is overcapacity in the Danish fleet. Danish fisheries management is characterised by the availability of extensive data; i.e., the Danish managers have information about the landings at the trip level and costs at the vessel level. With available information it would be possible to distribute rations to ensure a welfare optimum, where marginal revenue is equal to marginal costs. In the long-run, capacity reduction could be sustained by use of decommissioning programmes, assuming that capital is nonmalleable. Restricted entry (license) is already implemented in the EU fisheries. The conclusion is, therefore, that with the available information, welfare improvements are possible, but the information must be better utilised if the aim is to maximize welfare. This constitutes an important area for future research. References Andersen, P. 1979. Fiskeriøkonomi. Esbjerg, Denmark: South Jutland University Press. Anon. 1999. Fiskeriregnskabsstatistik. Copenhagen, Denmark: Danish Research Institute of Food Economics. _. 2000. Report of the Working Group on the Assessment of Demersal Stocks in the North Sea and Skagerak. Copenhagen, Denmark: ICES. Clark, C.W. 1990. Mathematical Bioeconomics. The Optimal Management of Renewable Resources. New York, NY: John Wiley and Sons. Dantzig, G.B. 1963. Linear Programming and Extensions. New Jersey: Princeton University Press. Frost H., and J. Andersen. 2001. Socioeconomic Evaluation of Effort Regulation Illustrated for Selected Danish Fisheries. Report no. 122. Copenhagen, Denmark: The Danish Institute of Agricultural and Fisheries Economics (in Danish). Harford, J.D. 1984. Relatively Efficient Pollution Standards under Perfect Competition. Public Finance Quarterly 12:183 95. Holden, M. 1996. The Common Fisheries Policy. Oxford: Fishing News Books. Homans, F.R., and J.E. Wilen 1997. A Model of Regulated Open Access Resource Use. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 32:1 21. Karagiannakos, A. 1995. Fisheries Management in the European Union. Aldershot, England: Avebury. Lynge-Jensen, C. 2000. A Critical Review of the Common Fisheries Policy. Department of Environmental and Business Economics, South Jutland University, Working Paper No. 6. Warming, J. 1911. Om Grundrente af Fiskegrunde. Nationaløkonomisk Tidsskrift 49:64 76.