Power-law distribution in Japanese racetrack betting

Similar documents
Using Actual Betting Percentages to Analyze Sportsbook Behavior: The Canadian and Arena Football Leagues

Working Paper No

Gamblers Favor Skewness, Not Risk: Further Evidence from United States Lottery Games

Staking plans in sports betting under unknown true probabilities of the event

Sportsbook pricing and the behavioral biases of bettors in the NHL

Kobe University Repository : Kernel

EFFICIENCY OF RACETRACK BETTING MARKETS. editors. Donald B Hausch. University of Wisconsin-Madison, USA. Victor SY Lo

BIASES IN ASSESSMENTS OF PROBABILITIES: NEW EVIDENCE FROM GREYHOUND RACES. Dek Terrell* August Abstract

Journal of Emerging Trends in Computing and Information Sciences

Mathematics of Pari-Mutuel Wagering

Information effects in major league baseball betting markets

Prediction Market and Parimutuel Mechanism

What Causes the Favorite-Longshot Bias? Further Evidence from Tennis

Original Article. Correlation analysis of a horse-betting portfolio: the international official horse show (CSIO) of Gijón

Structural Design and Analysis of the New Mobile Refuge Chamber

PROPAGATION OF LONG-PERIOD WAVES INTO AN ESTUARY THROUGH A NARROW INLET

Game, set and match: The favorite-long shot bias in tennis betting exchanges.

Special edition paper

Hot Hand or Invisible Hand: Which Grips the Football Betting Market?

DOWNLOAD PDF TELEPHONE NUMBERS THAT PROVIDE THE WINNING NUMBERS FOR EACH LOTTERY.

Tilburg University. Bets and Bids Potters, Jan; Wit, J. Publication date: Link to publication

The Velocity of Money Revisited

The key principle behind this system is as simple as it is brilliant find horses that are under-bet by the market, and then bet on them ourselves.

INCLINOMETER DEVICE FOR SHIP STABILITY EVALUATION

ISOLATION OF NON-HYDROSTATIC REGIONS WITHIN A BASIN

Friction properties of the face of a hand-held tennis racket

Critical Gust Pressures on Tall Building Frames-Review of Codal Provisions

Numerical and Experimental Investigation of the Possibility of Forming the Wake Flow of Large Ships by Using the Vortex Generators

Global Sports Betting Market

MODELING OF THERMAL BEHAVIOR INSIDE A BUBBLE

Rogue Wave Statistics and Dynamics Using Large-Scale Direct Simulations

Calculation of Trail Usage from Counter Data

Swinburne Research Bank

CS 5306 INFO 5306: Crowdsourcing and. Human Computation. Lecture 11. 9/28/17 Haym Hirsh

Sport Hedge Millionaire s Guide to a growing portfolio. Sports Hedge

CHAPTER IV FINITE ELEMENT ANALYSIS OF THE KNEE JOINT WITHOUT A MEDICAL IMPLANT

Experimental Verification of Integrated Pressure Suppression Systems in Fusion Reactors at In-Vessel Loss-of -Coolant Events

STATE OF NEW YORK OFFICE OF THE STATE COMPTROLLER 110 STATE STREET ALBANY, NEW YORK September 2015

EXPERIMENTAL STUDY ON THE HYDRODYNAMIC BEHAVIORS OF TWO CONCENTRIC CYLINDERS

Optimal Weather Routing Using Ensemble Weather Forecasts

Surprisals Revisited. Outcome Surprisal

In Search of Sure Things An Analysis of Market Efficiency in the NFL Betting Market

All the Mail Pay instructions will be clearly printed on the back of your winning ticket!

Legendre et al Appendices and Supplements, p. 1

Working Draft: Gaming Revenue Recognition Implementation Issue. Financial Reporting Center Revenue Recognition

Analysis of Shear Lag in Steel Angle Connectors

FORECASTING OF ROLLING MOTION OF SMALL FISHING VESSELS UNDER FISHING OPERATION APPLYING A NON-DETERMINISTIC METHOD

Framing Effects in the Field: Evidence from Two Million Bets

Assessment Schedule 2016 Mathematics and Statistics: Demonstrate understanding of chance and data (91037)

Modelling of French High Speed Train Evacuation

A CASE STUDY CONSIDERING A 3-D PUSHOVER ANALYSIS PROCEDURE

Determination of the Design Load for Structural Safety Assessment against Gas Explosion in Offshore Topside

Deciding When to Quit: Reference-Dependence over Slot Machine Outcomes

The Application of Pedestrian Microscopic Simulation Technology in Researching the Influenced Realm around Urban Rail Transit Station

Study on the shape parameters of bulbous bow of. tuna longline fishing vessel

Injector Dynamics Assumptions and their Impact on Predicting Cavitation and Performance

SCIENTIFIC COMMITTEE SEVENTH REGULAR SESSION August 2011 Pohnpei, Federated States of Micronesia

Engineering Models for Vented Lean Hydrogen Deflagrations

Novel empirical correlations for estimation of bubble point pressure, saturated viscosity and gas solubility of crude oils

Skewness is the name of the game

Influence of Forecasting Factors and Methods or Bullwhip Effect and Order Rate Variance Ratio in the Two Stage Supply Chain-A Case Study

Racetrack Betting: Do Bettors Understand the Odds?

Market Efficiency and Behavioral Biases in the WNBA Betting Market

Queue analysis for the toll station of the Öresund fixed link. Pontus Matstoms *

ScienceDirect. Rebounding strategies in basketball

A Failure of the No-Arbitrage Principle

Chance and Uncertainty: Probability Theory

Finite Element Modal Analysis of Twin Ball Screw Driving Linear Guide Feed Unit Table

Insurance. The practical application. of credibility models in the rating of Health

CFD Simulation and Experimental Validation of a Diaphragm Pressure Wave Generator

An approach to account ESP head degradation in gassy well for ESP frequency optimization

The impacts of football point systems on the competitive balance: evidence from some European footbal leagues

Ranking teams in partially-disjoint tournaments

Procedia Engineering 00 2 (2010) (2009) Properties of friction during the impact between tennis racket surface and ball

DOWNLOAD OR READ : WINNING SPORTS BETTING PDF EBOOK EPUB MOBI

Quantifying Bullwhip Effect and reducing its Impact. Roshan Shaikh and Mudasser Ali Khan * ABSTRACT

Design Optimization for the Discharge System of the Rotary Compressor Using Alternative Refrigerant R410a

WATER HYDRAULIC HIGH SPEED SOLENOID VALVE AND ITS APPLICATION

Opleiding Informatica

Elastic-Plastic Finite Element Analysis for Zhongwei--guiyang Natural Gas Pipeline Endangered by Collapse

Energy capture performance

STATE OF NEW YORK OFFICE OF THE STATE COMPTROLLER 110 STATE STREET ALBANY, NEW YORK September 2015

Using Markov Chains to Analyze a Volleyball Rally

Designing a Traffic Circle By David Bosworth For MATH 714

Honest Mirror: Quantitative Assessment of Player Performances in an ODI Cricket Match

WORKING GROUP ON STOCK ASSESSMENTS 5 TH MEETING DOCUMENT SAR-5-08 TARGET SIZE FOR THE TUNA FLEET IN THE EASTERN PACIFIC OCEAN

ROUNDABOUT CAPACITY: THE UK EMPIRICAL METHODOLOGY

CFD AND EXPERIMENTAL STUDY OF AERODYNAMIC DEGRADATION OF ICED AIRFOILS

Research on ESC Hydraulic Control Unit Property and Pressure Estimation

PROFIT RECALL 2 USER GUIDE

EFFECTS OF IMPORT AND INVENTORY AMOUNTS ON CHANGES IN WHOLESALE PRICES OF SALMON IN JAPAN

Simulation analysis of the influence of breathing on the performance in breaststroke

FISHERIES MANAGEMENT UNDER SPECIES ALTERNATION: CASE OF THE PACIFIC PURSE SEINER OFF JAPAN

Individual Behavior and Beliefs in Parimutuel Betting Markets

ASSESSMENT OF CORRECTNESS OF INFORMATION OBTAINED FROM AUTOMATIC IDENTIFICATION OF SHIP S SYSTEM (AIS)

A statistical model of Boy Scout disc golf skills by Steve West December 17, 2006

Well Control Modeling Software Comparisons with Single Bubble Techniques in a Vertical Well

TOWARD MORE ACCURATE PREDICTION OF DAMAGE DUE TO STRONG WINDS

Atmospheric Waves James Cayer, Wesley Rondinelli, Kayla Schuster. Abstract

EXPERIMENTAL ANALYSIS OF MECHANICAL PROPERTIES OF SELECTED TAKRAW BALLS IN MALAYSIA

Transcription:

Power-law distribution in Japanese racetrack betting Takashi Ichinomiya Nonlinear Studies and Computation, Research Institute for Electronic Science, Hokkaido University, Sapporo 060-0812, Japan. Abstract Gambling is one of the basic economic activities that humans indulge in. An investigation of gambling activities provides deep insights into the economic actions of people and sheds lights on the study of econophysics. In this paper we present an analysis of the distribution of the final odds of the races organized by the Japan Racing Association. The distribution of the final odds P o (x) indicates a clear power law P o (x) 1/x, where x represents the final odds. This power law can be explained on the basis of the assumption that that every bettor bets his money on the horse that appears to be the strongest in a race. Key words: econophysics, the efficient market, scaling PACS: 02.50, 05.40, 89.75.-k 1 Introduction Since Pascal proposed the theory of probability, the phenomenon of gambling have given inspirations to many mathematicians, physicists and economists. For example, economists have studied gambling activities in order to examine the market efficiency. If bettors try to maximize their expected rewards, it would be equivalent for every race and every horse. In this case, the gambling market is efficient, and there is no assured way to gain money. Gabriel and Marsden studied market efficiency in British racetrack betting and found this gambling market to be inefficient[1]. Russo, Gandar and Zuber conducted a similar study on the National Football League betting market[2]. They found no clear indication of breakdown of efficiency. These results are re-examined Cain et al. and Ioannidis and Peel by different methods[3,4] Email address: miya@nsc.es.hokudai.ac.jp (Takashi Ichinomiya). Preprint submitted to Elsevier Science 14 November 2005

Econophysics and financial engineering are other examples of studies that are closely related to gambling. It is true that gambling and trading differs. Though the stock value is determined by the action of traders, the bettors cannot determine the horse who win the race. However, the trading of stocks bears some similarity to gambling. In trading, traders speculate on stocks, attempt to predict which stock value will rise in the future. This is similar to gambling, in which bettors attempt to predict. Especially, the rewards of winners is determined by the decision of all bettors. This is similar to trading, in which the stock value is determined by the action of traders. Thus, the investigation of gambling will contribute to the advancement of econophysics. In this regards, Park and Domany reported the distribution of odds in Korean horse races[5]. They found the power-law distribution of the final odds. To explain this distribution, they proposed the model of betting, in which the bettors estimation of winning probability is affected by the odds. In this paper, we present an investigation of the distribution of the odds in horse racing in Japan, where national horse races are organized by the Japan Racing Association(JRA). The form of betting in horse race in Japan is same as the one in Korea. There is only one form of betting: pari-mutuel tote bet. In this betting system, the management expenses are deducted from the total amount of the bet, and the winners divide the remaining amount among themselves. In this paper, the odds is defined as the ratio of the reward to the bet. If we neglect the management expenses, the odds of a horse is given as total amount of the bed divided by amount of the bed on the horse. We show that the distribution of the final odds shows power law P o (x) x 1, where x represents the final odds. This is different from the one obtained by Park and Domany, P o (x) x 1.7. We propose the model to account for this power-law distribution. One interesting point of this model is that this powerlaw behavior is obtained by assuming bettors to be irrational. Here the word irrational means that bettors do not try to maximize their expected rewards. If we assume bettors to be rational, i. e. attempt to maximize expected rewards, we obtain power-law P o (x) x 2, which is different from empirical data. The outline of this paper is as follows. In the next section, we present the distribution of the final odds in horse races organized by the JRA. We show that the distribution of the final odds P o (x) and that of winners odds P w (x) exhibit power-law behaviors, P o (x) x 1 and P w (x) x 2. In section 3, we propose the model to account for this power-law distribution. In section 4, we make some discussion on our results. 2

0.1 distribution February 2005 March 2005 April 2005 May 2005 June 2005 July 2005 0.0001 1 10 100 1000 final odds Fig. 1. Distribution of the final odds between February and July 2005. 2 Investigation of the final odds in racing organized by the JRA We analyze the data of 1750 races organized by the JRA between February and July 2005. A total of 24493 horses participated in these races. For simplicity, we investigate only the odds of the win bets, without considering other bets such as dual forecasts or place bets. In Fig.1, we plot the distribution of the final odds P o (x) for each month, where x represents the final odds. It should be noted that this distribution is not one of the winning payouts; this figure shows the distribution of the final odds, including the losers odds. The distribution P o (x) for each month is very similar. At x < 100, P o (x) follows the power-law distribution, P o (x) x γ, and decays exponentially at x > 100. In order to obtain a clearer picture of the power-law distribution, we plot the total half-year distribution in Fig.2. This data indicates that γ 1. The distribution of the final winners odds is also interesting. In the same figure, we also plot the half-year distribution of winners odds. This data shows that the distribution of the winning payouts also follows the power law, P w (x) 1/x 2. It should be noticed that these data appear to be consistent with the efficiency of the gambling market. We assume that we bet on a horse whose final odds are represented by x. Then, the probability that the horse win is proportional to P w (x)/p o (x). Because the expected reward is represented by xp w (x)/p o (x), the empirical data shows that P w (x)/p o (x) is proportional to x and that the expected reward is independent of x. However, the efficiency of the gambling market does not mean the rationality of bettors. If bettors are rational, they will bet on the horse whose expected rewards is maximum, and the expected rewards will become equivalent for all horses. It is true that rationality of bettors is a sufficient condition for the efficient market, however, it is not a necessary condition. It should also be noted that the power-law distribution of the final odds cannot be explained solely by the rationality of bettors. We will need some other assumptions to explain the distribution. In the next section, we propose a model to account 3

Figure 2 1 odds winners odds distribution 0.1 y = 1/x 2 y = 1/x 1 10 100 1000 odds Fig. 2. Total distribution of the odds and the winners odds between February and July 2005. for these power-law distributions of the final odds. 3 Model simulation In this section, we propose a model to account for the distribution of the final odds. In order to construct the model, we must focus on the following points. First, the strength of each horse running in a race varies. One horse may be stronger than the other horses, and the weakest horse may perhaps lose the race. Therefore, we must include the differences in the strengths of horses in the model. Second, the strength of each horse provides the probability of winning. Even the strongest horse can lose the race if he is in poor health. Therefore, it appears natural to assume that the probability of winning is given by a function of the strength of the horse. Third, bettors are unaware of the exact strength of the horses. While they do know that some horses are stronger than the others, they do not know the exact strength and cannot precisely estimate the probability of winning. Considering these points, we propose the following model: (1) Each horse running in a race has a parameter called strength s, 0 < s 1. s i, the strength of horse i, is given by a uniform random number between 0 and 1. (2) Each bettor estimates the strength of horse i as s i + r i, where r i is the Gaussian random number. r i varies for each bettor, and the strength estimated by each bettor also differs. (3) Each bettor bets his money on the horse that appears to have the maximum strength in a race. As observed, bettors do not know the exact strength of the horses. They place their bets under incorrect estimation of the strength given by the previous rule. For simplicity, we assume that every bettor bets the same amount of money. (4) After each betting, x i, the odds of a horse i, is updated as x i = n tot /n i, 4

distribution 1 0.1 σ = 0.05 σ=0.5 σ=5.0 1 10 100 odds Fig. 3. Distribution obtained from our model at σ = 0.05, 0.5 and 5.0. Each distribution is obtained by simulating our model 1000 times. where n tot and n i represents the total number of bettors and number of bettors who bets on horse i, respectively. This rule means that we neglect the management expenses, and the total amount of bets is divided among the winners. This simplification does not lead to any problems. (5) The winning probability of a horse is proportional to his strength. This model has three parameters. The first parameter is the number of horses that participate in one race. Although the number of horses differs with each race, in the following simulation, we assume that 14 horses participate in one race. This approximates the average number of horses participate in one race, 13.996. The second parameter is the number of bettors. We set this number as 10000. The qualitative result of this simulation does not depend on the details of this parameter, if it is sufficiently large. The third parameter is σ, the dispersion of a random number r i. In our model, σ is the only parameter we should adjust for fitting. To see the σ-dependence of the distribution of the final odds, we plot the distribution P o (x) obtained by our model for some typical σ in Fig.3. If σ 1, almost all bettors bet on the strongest horse, and P o (x) shows sharp peak at x = 1. On the other hand, if σ 1 the strength of horse scarcely affects the choice of bettors. Every bettor bets on the horse almost at random, and P o will show sharp peak at x = h tot, where h tot is the total number of horses. The results of simulation at σ = 0.05 and σ = 5.0 shown in Fig.3 are consistent with this qualitative discussion. Though the region where P (x) 1/x appears in both cases, these results do not qualitatively coincide with empirical data. In the following of this paper, we use σ = 0.5 and compare the empirical data and the result of simulation. We calculate the distribution of the final odds at σ = 0.5 by simulating this model 10000 times. The results of the simulation are shown in Figs. 4 and 5. With regard to the distribution of the final odds shown in Fig.4, both the power-law behavior at x < 100 and the exponential decay at x > 100 are reproduced well in our model and are represented by squares. On the other hand, the power-law behavior of the distribution of the winners odds shown in 5

Figure 3 1 0.1 distribution empirical data simulation simulation 2 0.0001 1 10 100 1000 final odds Fig. 4. Comparison of the empirical distribution of the final odds and model calculation. Circles, squares and crosses represent the empirical data, the result of the model simulation and the result of the model simulation in which bettors attempt to maximize their expected rewards, respectively. Fig.5 is also reproduced by the simulation, although the absolute value differs slightly. These results suggest the validity of our model. However, the economists who believe in the rationality of people will expect that the bettors attempt to maximize their expected returns. If this is true, the bettors bet their money on the horse whose expected rewards (winning probability multiplied by odds) is maximum, instead of betting on the one whose probability of winning is maximum. However, the simulation shows that the empirical data cannot be accounted for by using the maximize the expected rewards model. In the maximize the expected rewards model, we use the following rule instead of the rule (3) in our model: (3 ) Each bettor bets his money on the horse that appears to have the maximum expected rewards in a race. Because the probability that a horse wins is proportional to his strength, the expected reward of horse i seems proportional to (n tot + 1)(s i + r i )/(n i + 1). Bettors bets his money on the horse i that seems to have maximum expected reward. Here we note that the expected rewards is not n tot (s i + r i )/n i, because if the bettor bets on the horse i, the odds of the horse changes from n tot /n i to (n tot + 1)/(n i + 1). In this model, the distribution of the odds is not δ-function even if r i = 0, because bettors bet on the weak horse with high odds. If the number of bettors is large enough, the expected rewards x i s i will be same for all horses. The result of the simulation based on this model is indicated by the cross in Figs. 4 and 5. In this maximize the expected rewards calculation, we take σ =. In this model, the distribution of the final odds P o (x) and winners odds P w (x) are approximately proportional to 1/x 2 and 1/x 3, respectively. These results are inconsistent with the empirical data. 6

Figure 4 1 0.1 distribution empirical data simulation simulation 2 0.0001 1 10 100 1000 winners odds Fig. 5. Comparison between the empirical distribution of the winners odds and model calculation. Circles, squares and crosses represent the empirical data, the result of the model simulation, and the result of the model simulation in which bettors attempt to maximize their expected rewards, respectively. 4 Conclusion and Discussion We investigate the distribution of the final odds in horse races organized by the JRA. The distribution of the final odds shows the clear power-law P o (x) x 1 at x < 100. The distribution of the winners odds also shows a power-law behavior, P w (x) x 2. In order to explain these distributions, we propose a model for the action of bettors. Numerical simulation of this model shows good agreement with the observation. These results show that the actions of the bettors in gambling can be described by our simple model. In particular, it should be noted that our model does not consider the bettors to be rational. In economics, a rational person will attempt to maximize his expected rewards and bet on the horse whose expected rewards appear to be maximum. In the usual model of the efficient market, the efficiency is guaranteed by this rationality. On the other hand, in our model bettors bet on the horse whose winning probability is maximum. Bettors do not bet on the weak horse, even if the odds are extremely high. Of course, we may be able to make the model to explain the distribution of odds, assuming rational bettors. For example, the different distribution of strength of horses s i will give the different distribution of the final odds. However, such a model will be more complicated one than our model. Therefore it seems natural to conclude that bettors are irrational in horse-racing. The inconsistency between our investigation and that of Park et al.[5] is also interesting. They studied the odds in Korean horse races and found the powerlaw distribution of the final odds, P o (x) x 1.7. To explain this power-law distribution, the assumed that bettors overestimate the probability of winning of the horse whose odds is small. Due to this effect, bettors overestimate the winning probability of strong horse. Both of their empirical data and simulation model are different from ours. In Japanese horse races, the distribution of odds shows different power-law, P o (x) x 1. One of the possible origin of 7

this difference is the difference in the distribution of the strength of horse. As we noticed, the different distribution of the strength of horses will give the different distribution of the final odds. However, it will be difficult to obtain the distribution of the strength from empirical data. We also note that the model of Parks et al. cannot explain our empirical data even if the distribution of strength is changed. As noticed above, their model assumes that the winning probabilities of strong horses are overestimated. If it is true, we can obtain larger expected rewards when we bet on the horse with large odds. However, our data show that the expected rewards is almost independent from odds. Our paper will shed light on the understanding of other economic activities of people, such as those in the financial market. The dynamics of the financial market is one of the main concern in econophysics. In this regards, the understanding of the action of traders plays the crucial role. If we know the action of each trader, we can make a reliable model to emulate the market. In this paper, we construct a model of bettors in gambling market, which can explain the distribution of the final odds very well. The knowledge obtained from the study of gambling market will give important information to the understanding of the financial market. Acknowledgments We are grateful to Takashi Teramoto, Jun-Ichi Fukuda, Yumino Hayase, Makoto Iima and Tatsuo Yanagita for the fruitful discussion. References [1] P. E. Gabriel and J. R. Marsden, The Journal of Political Economy 98 (1990) 874. [2] B. Russo, J. M. Gandar, and R. A. Zuber. Market rationality tests based crossequation restrictions. Journal of Monetary Economics, 24 (1989) 455. [3] M. Cain, D. Law, and D. Peel, Journal of Forecasting, 19 (2000) 575. [4] C. Ioannidis and D. Peel, Economics Letters, 87 (2005) 221. [5] K. Park and E. Domany, Europhysics Letters, 53 (2001) 419. 8