New Balance The weighty issues of salary caps, revenue sharing and luxury taxes in professional sports leagues

Similar documents
N.F.L. Collective Bargaining Agreement and an Uncapped Year Questions that Professional Football Fans Need Answers To. Outline for Sports Panel

THERE S NO I IN TEAM

The Catch-Up Rule in Major League Baseball

The Economics of Sports. Chapter 5. Competitive Balance MICHAEL A. LEEDS PETER VON ALLMEN FIFTH EDITION

Efficiency Wages in Major League Baseball Starting. Pitchers Greg Madonia

MLB, MLBPA ANNOUNCE DETAILS OF NEW LABOR AGREEMENT Parties Maintain Streak of More Than Two Decades Without a Work Stoppage

The Professional Sports Wives Magazine

The NHL Lockout BEM 106 Final Paper

NEW BALLPARK PLANNING STUDY

Economic Transformation and Recovery in Hong Kong and Singapore

STATE OF NEW YORK OFFICE OF THE STATE COMPTROLLER 110 STATE STREET ALBANY, NEW YORK September 2015

AMERICAN GREEN INC INTERIM FINANCIAL STATEMENTS

STATE OF NEW YORK OFFICE OF THE STATE COMPTROLLER 110 STATE STREET ALBANY, NEW YORK September 2015

Predicting the Total Number of Points Scored in NFL Games

What Exactly is Sports Economics? What is Sports Econ?

How to Explain Car Rental to Banks and Investors

Professional Sports Teams & Organizations

AMERICAN GREEN INC INTERIM FINANCIAL STATEMENTS

AMERICAN GREEN INC INTERIM FINANCIAL STATEMENTS (UNAUDITED)

The relationship between payroll and performance disparity in major league baseball: an alternative measure. Abstract

Using Actual Betting Percentages to Analyze Sportsbook Behavior: The Canadian and Arena Football Leagues

TREND INSIGHTS CABLE TO TELEVISE NCAA MEN S BASKETBALL CHAMPIONSHIP GAME

Lesson 2 Pre-Visit Big Business of the Big Leagues

Columbia University. Department of Economics Discussion Paper Series. Auctioning the NFL Overtime Possession. Yeon-Koo Che Terry Hendershott

2013 Hockey Arbitration Competition of Canada

PLAYER SALES, TRADE OF PLAYERS

The Salmon Industry: Twenty-Five Predictions for the Future

THE ECONOMIC CONTRIBUTION FROM HORSES

Collective Bargaining Agreement Cba Mlb

Economics of Professional Sport

Paul M. Sommers And Justin R. Gaines. March 2010 MIDDLEBURY COLLEGE ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER NO

Income Inequality in American Professional Sports Leagues

Clarkson University: Report on Athletic Program Participation Rates and Financial Support Data July 1, 2015 to June 30, 2016

Clarkson University: Report on Athletic Program Participation Rates and Financial Support Data July 1, 2017 to June 30, 2018

Clarkson University: Report on Athletic Program Participation Rates and Financial Support Data July 1, 2016 to June 30, 2017

Carolina Panthers: Changing Gas Station Strategies in Charlotte

Online Baseball Union

IN THE MATTER OF SALARY ARBITRATION BETWEEN: LARS ELLER -AND- THE MONTREAL CANADIENS SUBMISSION ON BEHALF OF LARS ELLER TEAM 21

The Economic Outlook. Economic Policy Division

Billy Beane s Three Fundamental Insights on Baseball and Investing

Effect of homegrown players on professional sports teams

FEDERAL BASEBALL LEAGUE OFFICIAL RULE BOOK

Inequality in America : The 1% in International and Historical Perspective

2013 NSLNC FIRST ROUND: Line Change

IN THE MATTER OF SALARY ARBITRATION BETWEEN: CODY FRANSON -AND- THE TORONTO MAPLE LEAFS SUBMISSION ON BEHALF OF CODY FRANSON TEAM 21

YOUTH CRICKET MASTERS TOURNAMENT DOMESTIC CRICKET WOMEN S CRICKET. Premium Cricket. Unlocking the potential in cricket betting

Retrenchment or Stagnation: Lessons from Japan s Lost Decades. Andrew Smithers. UK-Japan 21 st Century Group Conference 3 rd May, 2013

A market in which freedom is limited by a reserve rule distributes players about as a free market would.

Hunter and Angler Expenditures, Characteristics, and Economic Effects, North Dakota,

INTERIM FINANCIAL STATEMENTS

Livio Di Matteo, Lakehead University Talk Prepared for the Thunder Bay (Port Arthur) Rotary, November 27 th, 2018

Fantasy Basketball. Project Guidelines:

He Got Game Theory: A Melodrama

Exploring the Impacts of Salary Allocation on Team Performance

The Economic Outlook. Economic Policy Division

Index. E East Coast Hockey League (ECHL), 21 Easterlin s hypothesis, Employer discrimination, 98, 106 Entry discrimination, 96, 134

Europe June Craig Menear. Chairman, CEO & President. Diane Dayhoff. Vice President, Investor Relations

BABE: THE SULTAN OF PITCHING STATS? by. August 2010 MIDDLEBURY COLLEGE ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER NO

News English.com Ready-to-use ESL / EFL Lessons

Understanding the. Dr. Christopher Waller. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Fact Sheet for Q3 and January-September 2012 October 24, 2012

JEFF SAMARDZIJA CHICAGO CUBS BRIEF FOR THE CHICAGO CUBS TEAM 4

NFL1. Do you think television shows, in general, are getting better or getting worse?

2014 Tulane Baseball Arbitration Competition Josh Reddick v. Oakland Athletics (MLB)

ROLLER DERBY DEMOGRAPHICS:

Bob Costello Chief Economist & Vice President American Trucking Associations. Economic & Motor Carrier Industry Update.

2012 NSLNC ROUND ONE. Donovan s Galaxy GENERAL FACTS FOR BOTH TEAMS

A comment on recent events, and...

Jenrry Mejia v. New York Mets Submission on Behalf of New York Mets Midpoint: $2.6 Million Submission by Team 18

It s Past Time to Pay College Athletes

Vincent Viola and his partner Douglas Cifu acquired the Florida Panthers on September 27, 2013

Brookfield Asset Management O AK T R E E ACQUISITION M A R C H 1 3,

EC 250 Second lecture Outline: 1. Complete team sign-up 2. Team assignment 3. Logistics of FFL 4. League constitution

Table of Contents I. Introduction and Request for Hearing Decision... 2 Chart 1.1 Comparable Player Salaries... 3 II. Player Profile... 3 III.

From Reality to Concept to Reality Territorial Approaches in Rural Development

The Future of Major League Baseball in Canada by Glen Hodgson and Mario Lefebvre July 2011

Salary Arbitration, A Burden or a Benefit. By Bill Gilbert SABR 36. Seattle, Washington. June 29, 2006

Commodity Endowment Funds

Independent Economic Analysis Board. Review of the Estimated Economic Impacts of Salmon Fishing in Idaho. Task Number 99

Last Revised 5/27/2018

Sport Hedge Millionaire s Guide to a growing portfolio. Sports Hedge

Capital Beltway HOT Lanes - Frequently Asked Questions

FRANCHISE DEVELOPMENT KIT

The NHL and its players' association have a bit more than two weeks remaining to figure out how to share all the money the game generates.

NHL SALARY DETERMINATION AND DISTRIBUTION A THESIS. Presented to. The Colorado College. Bachelor of Arts. Ian Young. February 2015

Fit to Be Tied: The Incentive Effects of Overtime Rules in Professional Hockey

2014 NATIONAL BASEBALL ARBITRATION COMPETITION ERIC HOSMER V. KANSAS CITY ROYALS (MLB) SUBMISSION ON BEHALF OF THE CLUB KANSAS CITY ROYALS

Growth Strategies and Dynamics in Developing Countries. Michael Spence Hamilton Project/CGD Forum Washington D.C. April 14, 2008

Sportsbook pricing and the behavioral biases of bettors in the NHL

2014 MAJOR LEAGUE LEAGUE BASEBALL ATTENDANCE NOTES

Equity in Athletics 2017 Institution: Rock Valley College (148380) User ID: E Screening Questions

Equity in Athletics 2016 Institution: Rock Valley College (148380) User ID: E Screening Questions

2012 Hockey Arbitration Competition of Canada

Equity in Athletics Screening Questions

Hot Hand or Invisible Hand: Which Grips the Football Betting Market?

Team 1. Lars Eller vs. Montreal Canadiens. Submissions on behalf of Montreal Canadiens (Team Side)

Basic Wage for Soccer Players in Japan :

Equity in Athletics 2015 Institution: Rock Valley College (148380) User ID: E Screening Questions

National and Virginia Economic Outlook Professor Robert M. McNab Dragas Center for Economic Analysis and Policy Strome College of Business

Equity in Athletics 2017 Institution: Trinity College of Florida (137962) User ID: E Screening Questions

Transcription:

New Balance The weighty issues of salary caps, revenue sharing and luxury taxes in professional sports leagues By Andrew Zimbalist TThe titans are restless. After nearly two decades of labor peace, the owners of National Football League teams and the players union are once again squaring off. And in the push and shove of negotiations, the NFL s cap on total team salaries which many observers believe is the linchpin of the most functional system for managing the economics of professional league sports could be discarded. Should you care? If you are a football fan, certainly. But even if you are not, the salary cap issue offers a fascinating perspective into the ways in which sports leagues weigh the need for competitive balance against more immediate concerns about how the incredible riches created by modern marketing and mass media coverage are divided. tk 58 The Milken Institute Review

tk Fourth Quarter 2008 59

sports league balance the level playing field Start with the reality that success for sports leagues depends on reasonable competitive balance. That is, there must be significant uncertainty in the outcome of both individual contests and in league competition to keep fans coming (and paying). There must also be enough opportunity for improvement in team performance to prevent franchises from becoming perennial bottom dwellers in their leagues, lest entire regions of the country abandon the sport. At first blush, the problem of creating and maintaining balance in a truly competitive environment seems intractable. The cities in which teams are located vary enormously in size, interest and wealth, yet all compete in the same market for players. How can a smallmarket team with $50 million in local revenue hold its own in buying talent against a large-market team with $400 million in local revenue? Leagues use a variety of methods to achieve balance, with both varying success and varying consequences for the division of the financial pie among teams and players. One method seems pretty straightforward: all professional leagues in the United States use a reverse-order draft for first signings of amateur players, giving the teams that finish last the right to pick first. Or maybe not so straightforward: the National Basketball Association uses a modified version of this formula in order to reduce any incentive that teams low in the standings may have to lose even more games toward season s end. Each of the professional leagues in the United States also employs a system of revenue sharing in which the richer clubs transfer a portion of their earnings to the poorer ones. The NFL s system is the most comprehensive, shuffling around approximately three-quarters of leaguewide revenue. Major League Baseball follows, and this shared largesse is growing rapidly. Along with distributing $30 million-plus yearly to each club from its national media and property-contract revenue, Major League Baseball has a supplementary system that will transfer almost $400 million in 2008 from the top-revenue teams to the bottom-revenue teams. This year, the largest payer will contribute around $120 million and the largest payee will receive around $40 million under the supplementary system. Thus, the poorer baseball teams are virtually guaranteed some $70 million in revenue each before they sell a single ticket. Indeed, if a team lowballs its pay- previous page and this page: nigel buchanan Andrew Zimbalist teaches economics at Smith College in Massachusetts and writes extensively about sports. 60 The Milken Institute Review

roll, it is almost guaranteed a profit a reality implying that revenue sharing alone does not provide adequate incentives for competitive balance. the delicate business of salary caps Enter the aforementioned idea of salary caps, which are currently used in professional football, basketball, hockey and soccer in the United States. The cap is a limit on total payroll per team (not per player), and is generally formulated as a percentage of league-wide revenue divided by the number of teams. By setting both upper and lower limits, salary caps (and floors) tend to reduce variation in individual salaries and to compress team payrolls, interfering with the way a free market would allocate players across teams. Since individual players are likely to generate more value to large-market teams than to small-market ones think of it as the classic marginal-revenue product, from Economics 101 the enforcement of a payroll ceiling cuts the revenue advantage that naturally accrues to large-market clubs. Thus, to the extent that a player s performance can be predicted, the result is a more-equal distribution of talent around the league. Of course, the other important attribute of salary caps one that is often foremost in the minds of owners and the players negotiators is that they can serve as an effective instrument to reduce average player compensation. Note the difference in impact between salary caps and revenue sharing. Sharing revenue under a system with a uniform tax rate across the teams (as is practiced in Major Fourth Quarter 2008 61

sports league balance League Baseball) doesn t change the economic reality that the impact on team revenue of employing a star player will vary with the size of the team s local market. Thus, with or without revenue sharing, star player A is likely to generate more revenue for the New York Yankees than if he were playing for the Pittsburgh Pirates, giving the Yankees a strong incentive to outbid the Pirates. So while revenue sharing makes it more profitable to own a small-city franchise, it doesn t necessarily promote competitive balance. Revenue sharing, after all, reduces the marginal-revenue product of individual players to their own teams, and thus reduces the maximum salary it is worth paying to hire players. What a standard revenue-sharing system does, however, is shift income from players to owners. Revenue sharing, after all, reduces the marginal-revenue product of individual players to their own teams, and thus reduces the maximum salary it is worth paying to hire players. Think, for example, of a player whose presence could bring in an extra $10 million in ticket sales and other revenue to a team. If the team faced a 40 percent marginal tax rate if it were forced to share 40 percent of this extra $10 million the most a rational team owner would be willing to pay to hire the player would fall from $10 million to $6 million. In 2006, baseball made the tax rate uniform (previously it had varied according to relative team revenue) and lowered the rate to around 31 percent. The modification seemingly led to a notable increase in balance, as some perennial losers have since become winners. Baseball s balance has also been aided by the introduction of the wild-card berth in the mid-1990s, which adds two additional teams to postseason competition, and by the growing efficiency of some smallermarket teams in getting more performance for less money. In an average year, the variance in baseball payrolls accounts for about 20 percent of the variance in winning percentage the highest correlation between payroll and performance among American team sports. This means, of course, that roughly 80 percent of the variance in winning percentage is explained by factors other than payroll; thus, large-market teams might have a leg up, but they are hardly guaranteed success. Baseball had fiddled with the balance calculus by adding a luxury tax and debt limits. The tax is imposed on teams whose payroll exceeds a stated threshold $155 million this year. The only team with a payroll exceeding this figure is the Yankees, which shells out $209 million in salaries (plus approximately $22 million in luxury taxes). The debt rules cap the amount of debt a team may incur relative to its earnings, as well as require teams to set aside cash to cover deferredcompensation obligations to players. The Major League Baseball Players Association has always strenuously resisted team salary caps, accepting crippling work stoppages in order to prevent their imposition. Today, baseball is the only major sports league in the United States that does not have a salary cap. It is unclear, however, whether the players resistance has paid off. Salaries represented just 51 percent of Major League Baseball s $5.7 billion revenue in 2007, compared to 67 percent of $3.4 billion in 2002. Indeed, 62 The Milken Institute Review

football, basketball and hockey, which all operate under salary cap systems, devote a higher percentage of revenue to salaries (between 56 and 60 percent) than does baseball. This paradoxical outcome is more apparent than real. Baseball, unlike football and basketball, supports a player-development system through its minor league affiliates. And more than 6 percent of Major League Baseball s revenue went toward these minor league player salaries. If this is added to the Major League players salary share, total player compensation rises to 57 percent. Baseball s salary-revenue ratio is also influenced by the peculiar posting system that the league maintains with Japan s Nippon Professional Baseball league. Under the agreement, teams get to bid for the right to negotiate with a posted Japanese player. The winning bidder must pay the bid price to the player s Japanese team if it manages to reach a deal with the player (an arrangement not unlike the way baseball owners skimmed the value from traded players before an arbitrator forced an end to the practice in 1976). To take a glaring example, before the 2007 season, the Boston Red Sox paid $101 million for Daisuke Matsuzaka s services over six years, but $51 million of this went to the Seibu Lions. And that $51 million isn t counted in the official tally of the Red Sox player compensation. less than meets the eye These adjustments put baseball in the same salary-share range as the sports with formal team salary caps, implying that, counter to conventional wisdom, a negotiated salary cap does not necessarily favor owners over players in the division of the revenues in professional leagues. That raises two prominent questions. First, in light of the fact that a salary cap system would, at least in theory, better promote competitive balance than the current luxury tax, wouldn t it make sense for baseball s Players Association to abandon its long, costly fight against the institution? By the same token, does it really make sense for the NFL owners (who certainly need competitive balance to sustain a successful collective business) to put the league s salary cap system on the negotiating table? Muddying the analytic waters here, salary caps have come to mean different things in different sports. The cap in the NBA has long been a soft cap. Since its inception in the 1984-85 season, when the cap was set at 48 percent of defined gross revenue (basically ticket and television revenue), the NBA s cap has had a significant loophole, known as the (Larry) Bird Exception: The salary paid to a player who signs a new contract with the team he is currently playing for doesn t count against the cap. This exception enabled some teams to spend more than twice the actual cap. Not surprisingly, that cap did little to control salaries or to promote competitive balance though it may have reduced player mobility. After a protracted lockout in 1998 and 1999, the players agreed to a new system that supplemented the soft cap with an escrow tax (directly on players salaries) and a luxury tax (on team spending for salaries). The incentives created by these taxes have effectively corralled player compensation, so that it has settled at a steady 57 percent of basketball-related income, a more comprehensive measure of NBA revenue. The NFL salary cap has been in place since 1994. Until 2006, it was set as a share of defined gross revenue, but is now established at 59.5 percent of total leaguewide revenue. The NFL players were the first to suggest a salary cap, in the early 1980s. They did this because there was (and is) so much revenue-sharing in the league that teams, in effect, have no financial incentive to win. With little reason for Fourth Quarter 2008 63

sports league balance teams to pay top value for players, the players association saw a salary cap system (which, critically, also came with a salary floor) as a way to guarantee that the players would receive a fair share of the revenue that they generated. The NFL cap has also proved to be somewhat porous in the short run. Teams are allowed to pay players via signing bonuses as well as salaries. And for purposes of salary cap calculations, signing bonuses are amortized over the nominal life of a player s contract. For example, a team could sign a player to a five-year contract that included a signing bonus of $15 million and an annual salary of $2 million. The signing bonus would count as only $3 million toward the first year s cap, along with the $2 million salary. Thus, even though the team paid the player $17 million in the first year, only $5 million of it would count toward the cap. Note that a team could pursue this strategy with multiple players in successive years and thereby manage to maintain a cash payroll above the salary cap for many years. Nonetheless, the team would be accruing a backlog of unamortized bonuses that would eventually force it to keep current payroll below the cap. Because teams are obliged to make up for overages down the road, the NFL system is generally regarded as a hard cap. Under the NFL s 2006 contract, there is an additional mechanism to ensure that the league does not consistently spend more than 59.5 percent of total revenue on salaries. If the league goes above that level, any team exceeding that percentage will have to make up the overage in the following year. The salary cap in the National Hockey nigel buchanan 64 The Milken Institute Review

League was introduced after the disastrous 2004-05 player lockout and only after the players union negotiator resigned. The NHL cap is set as a progressive share of hockey-related income: 54 percent when the total is below $2.2 billion and gradually rising to 57 percent when it is greater than $2.7 billion. The league cap will reach that top bracket this season. Accordingly, each team s payroll will be limited to $56.7 million next year. what s good for the goose As with the NFL and NBA, the NHL s cap is complemented by a floor in the NHL s case, $16 million below the cap in 2008-09. It is interesting that the NHL floor in 2008-09 is still well above the lowest team payroll in Major League Baseball in 2008 ($21.8 million for the Florida Marlins), which, as noted earlier, doesn t have a cap or a floor. Note, however, that while baseball allows team payrolls to be unlimited (albeit subject to a luxury tax), the openness goes both ways. Thus, the Yankees opening day payroll in 2008 was roughly 10 times that of the Marlins! Individual player salaries are, of course, indirectly constrained by the team caps in football, basketball and hockey. That limit is supplemented by rules that no player may receive more than 25 to 35 percent of the team cap in the NBA (depending on length of service) and 20 percent in the NHL. The leagues with caps also limit the number of years a player s contract may cover. Baseball, by contrast, has limited neither salary nor contract length, with sometimes-spectacular consequences: think of Alex Rodriguez 10-year contract with the Yankees, worth over $275 million. This, of course, gives baseball teams the latitude to take big risks risks that are generally undertaken only by high-revenue teams. When the 2002 baseball contract was being negotiated, the owners offered the Players Association a team salary floor of $40 million as part of the revenue-sharing system. The players rejected the offer for three reasons. First, it ran counter to the free-labor-market strategy that was the basis for the union s longstanding resistance to a salary cap. Second, the association feared that a salary floor would open the door to a salary cap. Third, the $40 million was so low only three teams were paying less that the players put little value in it. As it happened, more teams payrolls fell below the $40 million level in subsequent years, even as baseball s revenue was rising. The Players Association argues that the drop in the players share of revenue to 51 percent during the last two seasons is a product of the industry s rapid revenue growth, and that the players share will catch up as individual players contracts expire. Perhaps. It is equally likely, though, that a negotiated cap system would have left the players better off collectively than they are today, and in the process done more to improve baseball s competitive balance. A point to note here: the one thing an open market does that a cap system does not is to help players share in the value of synergies between the team and other businesses of the team owner. Owning an iconic sports team may allow an owner to create a successful regional sports network, a facility-management company or a concessionaire business. Or it may simply elevate the standing of an owner in the community, conferring significant business advantages. In such cases, the player may be more valuable to an owner than calculations made from team revenue implies. Accordingly, an open market may lead to higher payrolls, as well as to greater competitive imbalance. The Players Association has also argued that it wanted no part of a system limiting the humungous salaries paid to superstars. The Fourth Quarter 2008 65

sports league balance top players in football, basketball and hockey, after all, must content themselves with smaller, shorter-term deals. But there are plainly costs to this defense of the interests of the most desired players: greater inequality in pay, as well as less competitive balance. Complicating matters further, if a league relies heavily on revenue sharing to balance financial (as opposed to competitive) outcomes, it undermines owners incentives to invest in their teams via payroll, marketing, facility improvements or player development. fans in the middle While the economics of sports leagues is complex and probably ever in flux, it does seem clear that both players and owners share what amounts to a myth in the power of salary caps to determine the division of the pie between labor and management. The evidence suggests that owners can live without salary caps, while players can thrive with them. While some professional sports have done better than others in encouraging excellence, competitive balance and profitability, none has found a magic bullet. The politics of league governance, involving both conflicts among owners operating in vastly different markets and struggles between owners and players over the division of revenue between salaries and profits, make it likely that the interests of sports fans will at times take a back seat. m And the guy on the spine is... Wassily Leontief, winner of a Nobel Prize in 1973. Born in Germany of wealthy Russian parents, he was raised in what was then (and once again is) St. Petersburg. Leontief decamped for the less hostile climes of Weimar Germany in 1925, then made it to Harvard in 1932. Leontief was an anti-communist. But, ironically, his crowning intellectual achievement was an economic management tool input-output analysis that at the time (the 1940s and 1950s) was heralded as a technique that would make Soviet-style central planning more practical. In fact, the technique proved almost worthless in large-scale planning because (a) it required vast computational power in an era before the microprocessor was invented, and (b) it ignored the potential impact of price changes, implicitly assuming that there is only one way to combine inputs to make the thousands of good and services of a modern economy. Still, input-output analysis has proved useful in more modest roles for example, in testing the proposition that the relative scarcity of labor and capital determines what countries import and export. david smith 66 The Milken Institute Review