Can Roger do, what Roger can? Optimal serving in tennis

Similar documents
Existence of Nash Equilibria

The Effect of Pressure on Mixed-Strategy Play in Tennis: The Effect of Court Surface on Service Decisions

Professionals Play Minimax: Appendix

ECONOMICS DEPT NON - ASSESSED TEST. For Internal Students of Royal Holloway. Time Allowed: 1 hour. Instructions to candidates:

Benefits in effective scouting:

Game Theory (MBA 217) Final Paper. Chow Heavy Industries Ty Chow Kenny Miller Simiso Nzima Scott Winder

Politecnico di Torino. Porto Institutional Repository

FUBA RULEBOOK VERSION

Dynamic Matching Pennies with Asymmetries: An Application to NFL Play-Calling

Mohammad Hossein Manshaei 1393

TACTICAL FOOTBALL GAME RULEBOOK fubatacticalfootballgame. Game design by Hannu Uusitalo

Player Development. Journal

Player Development. Journal

CS/Ec101b (2005) Game Theory Module

We can use a 2 2 array to show all four situations that can arise in a single play of this game, and the results of each situation, as follows:

We can use a 2 2 array to show all four situations that can arise in a single play of this game, and the results of each situation, as follows:

OPTIMAL MIXED STRATEGY PLAY: PROFESSIONALS CAN, STUDENTS CANNOT, BUT WHAT ABOUT THE IN BETWEEN CASE?

U7 Soccer Program: FUNdamentals. Modified Laws for U7 Revised March 2019

On the advantage of serving first in a tennis set: four years at Wimbledon

Goldsmiths Company Mathematics Course for Teachers. Game Theory. Dr. Reto Mueller

MITES SOCCER LEAGUE MANUAL

ADVANCED TACTICS: CONCEPTS, FEATURES AND 5 GAME SITUATIONS

CYSA Coach s Training Guide


The Rule of Right-Angles: Exploring the term Angle before Depth

MERIDIAN SOCCER CLUB

Northern SC U12 Playing Formats 8v8 (7 field players + 1 GK)

A Basic Understanding of Soccer

Pre-Game: Review the age division specific rules for your game! Inspect your field of play, nets attached to goal, etc.

U11-U12 Activities & Games

Possession games, Youth Training Sessions. Accents U13s

ONE FOUR LOW - DRIBBLE DRIVE OFFENSE

Case Study: How Misinterpreting Probabilities Can Cost You the Game. Kurt W. Rotthoff Seton Hall University Stillman School of Business

5.1. Running on sand CHAPTER 5: TECHNIQUE TRAINING OUTFIELD PLAYERS MAIN COMPONENT. Beach Soccer

Planning and Acting in Partially Observable Stochastic Domains

U6 Division Game Rules

Introduction To Shooting & 1v1 & 2v2 Situations

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PROFESSIONALS DO NOT PLAY MINIMAX: EVIDENCE FROM MAJOR LEAGUE BASEBALL AND THE NATIONAL FOOTBALL LEAGUE

The Edge Sports Center, LLC Youth Indoor Soccer Rules (September 28, 2017)

Latham Circle Soccer Club Fall Recreation and Skills Program Coach s and Referee s Guide (Players in Grades 3 and up)

ECO 199 GAMES OF STRATEGY Spring Term 2004 Precept Materials for Week 3 February 16, 17

Detecting Match-Fixing in Tennis

Copyright Notice - IT IS ILLEGAL TO POST THIS DOCUMENT ONLINE

Arlington Recreation Rules

Teachers: Samantha Coles & Roland Wilson. Phys. Ed. Block Plan 2019 Unit 1: Football Week 1 Week 4 02/11-03/08 Day 1: Football Passing and Catching

Hardin Simmons University University Recreation Department

PLEA th Conference, Opportunities, Limits & Needs Towards an environmentally responsible architecture Lima, Perú 7-9 November 2012

Season By Daniel Mattos GLSA Futsal Director FUTSAL

Testing Mixed Strategy Equilibria When Players. Are Heterogeneous: The Case of Penalty Kicks. in Soccer

Revisiting the Hot Hand Theory with Free Throw Data in a Multivariate Framework

Active for Life: GAG Activity

Oroville Youth Soccer Club Coaching Guide

NHSA Practice Plans. Mark Ruest NHSA Director of Coaching

LAW 11 Offside Review

Developing Support Play and Encouraging Players to Time Their Runs

1 Copyright 2011 Metro Strategy Group LLC

The Tennis Player s Posture The Value of Balance

Weekly Practice Schedule:

The final set in a tennis match: four years at Wimbledon 1

EDMONTON MINOR SOCCER ASSOCIATION

Teacher: Samantha Coles. Phys. Ed. Block Plan 2019 Unit 1: Football Week 1 Week 4 02/11-03/08 Day 1: Football Passing and Catching

WESTON SOCCER CLUB FALL CURRICULUM 5th & 6th Grade

Season. Soccer Rule Book

ABAB OR ABBA? THE ARITHMETICS OF PENALTY SHOOTOUTS IN SOCCER.

Averages. October 19, Discussion item: When we talk about an average, what exactly do we mean? When are they useful?

Oakville Soccer Club Winter Champions League Cup

Small Sided Games SHARP SHOOTER

GO NOW Players divided into two groups of up to six players each.

AGES 16 / 18 AND UNDER. Small Area Games LESSON WORKBOOK ROGER GRILLO

Northern SC U6 Playing Format 3v3

Coaching Players Ages 17 to Adult

An inspection game model of the stolen base in baseball: A theory of theft 1

Mini Soccer What Game Format and Development Model is Best?

ASSISTANT REFEREE TRAINING 2015

Red, White & Blue Hockey!

The Rules of Indoor Soccer Summary of Changes

Spring 2010 Coaching Sessions U14

2018 ADULT INDOOR SOCCER RULES AND REGULATIONS

REC SOCCER LEAGUE MANUAL

In this session we look at developing teams ability to defend as a unit.

INDOOR SOCCER RULES Updated: March 13, 2018

HOMELESS WORLD CUP STREET SOCCER RULES

Mite/Squirt Hockey Drills

Referee Positioning. Ohio South Referee Recertification Training

SENIOR PHYSICAL EDUCATION BASELINE DATA ASSESSMENT

Minimax Play at Wimbledon

Imperceptibly off-center goalkeepers influence penalty-kick direction in soccer

The Review of Economic Studies Ltd.

Technical and tactical analysis of the Olympic tournament London November AEFCA Symposium in Split Dany Ryser

1. OVERVIEW OF METHOD

USSOCCER.COM OFFSIDE MADE EASY

Advantages and Disadvantages of Systems of Play

The Rules of The Game

AGES 14 AND UNDER. Small Area Games LESSON WORKBOOK ROGER GRILLO

Basic Field Hockey Rules and Concepts

Football. English for THE GAMES

Axiomatic decomposition of a zero-sum game: the penalty shoot-out case

The Progression from 4v4 to 11v11

1. Teach kids to sit on their ball and listen to your coaching

Attacking. Soccer. Mastering the Modern Game. Norbert Elgert. Peter Schreiner/

Transcription:

Can Roger do, what Roger can? Institut für Soziologie, Universität Leipzig and Schweizerischer Nationalfonds contact: berger@sozio.uni-leipzig.de Seminar at Venice International University, San Servolo, December, 3-7, 2007

Rational decision in zero-sum games In standard theory rational deciding consists of two elements: 1 Completely selfish preferences, and 2 the (cognitive) ability to decide in order to maximise the corresponding utility. In zero- (or constant) sum games the interests of the actors are by definition contrary to each other. So, the first condition is always fulfilled. The problem of rational decision therefore is constrained to find and follow the utility maximising strategy, say the Minimax solution.

A simple example: Matching pennies The pursuer tries to catch the evader. That one tries to hide in- or outside. If they meet the pursuer wins. If not, the evader does. pursuer in out evader in 1 1 1 1 out 1 1 1 1 pursuer: {in/in} > {out/in} {in/out} < {out/out} evader: {in/in} < {in/out} {out/in} > {out/out} Minimax solution: Both chose in or out with a probability of 0.5.

Where does the rationality com from in such a case? Two concepts: 1 Rationality is an individual property, acquired by reinforced learning in a certain interaction. Rational decision then might happen rather subconsciously (Raab und Johnson 2006). The more often an actor has run through an interaction, the closer to optimum his decisions should be (H1). The simpler an interaction is (e.g. less vs more options), the closer to optimum decisions should be (H2). 2 Rationality is an emergent,,,ecological property of the interaction structure (Becker 1962, Coleman 1986/1990, Smith 2003). So, in highly competitive interactions are (e.g. zero-sum games) decisions should be close to optimum (H3).

Minimax play in the field Minimax play in the laboratory I: Minimax play of professional tennis players (H1/H3) Hsu et al. (2007) find optimal play for a selection of male, female, and junior players. Walker/Wooders (2001) find optimal play for a selection of male players. Klaasen/Magnus (2001) find for all Wimbledon games from 1992-1995 that stronger players are closer to optimum, than weaker ones, though none of them completely reaches it.

Minimax play in the field Minimax play in the laboratory I: Minimax play of professional football players (H1/H3) Chiappori et al. (2002) and Palacios-Huerta (2003) find optimal mixture between left and right in penalty kicks for a selection of penalty kicks from major European leagues. Berger/Hammer (2007) find optimal mixture between left and right in all penalty kicks for the goalkeepers and close to optimum play by the strikers in the Bundesliga from 1993 to 2004. Moschini (2004) finds optimal mixture between left and right for shooting from wing position to the goal in the Serie A. Berger (mimeo) finds mixed evidence for the strategies (left, center, right) of goalkeepers in penalty kicks. While goalies in the Bundesliga act optimal, goalies in other European leagues do so only in tendency.

Minimax play in the field Minimax play in the laboratory IV: Minimax play in the laboratory by untrained actors (see Berger/Hammer 2007 for literature) Generally humans do not easy randomize decisions in laboratory experiments and tend to form patterns. Subjects tend to fail the more complex the game is (e.g. in 4 4 games rather than in 2 2 games)(h2). Generally untrained actors tend to fail in mixing their actions, though they get better, after having repeatedly played the game (H1).

Minimax play in the field Minimax play in the laboratory II: Minimax play in the laboratory by trained actors Professional and amateur football players act optimal in the laboratory, in a game where lay people fail (Palacios-Huerta / Volji 2006) (H1). But, Levitt et al. (2007) find no evidence that professional poker, bridge, football players did play any better than lay people in the same laboratory games. This was the case though mixing actions is crucial for skillfully playing poker, is of certain importance for football players (not only in penalty kicks), but plays no role in bridge (H1/H3).

Summary of the the know evidence Minimax play in the field Minimax play in the laboratory + : Minimax play confirmed : Minimax play not confirmed field laboratory professionals I: + + II: + amateurs III:?? IV:

Amateurs acting in the field: Serving in tennis The serving player in tennis brings the ball into play, by hitting it from behind of one side of his field across to the the serving field of the receiving player. The receiving player expects the ball standing wherever he wants on his side of the net, and tries to hit back the ball wherever he wants to in the field of the server. As soon as one player fails to hit back the ball into his opponent s field according to the rules, the other one makes the point.

Decision problem while serving in tennis Following Walker/Wooders (2001) and Hsu et al. (2007) the server s decision is modeled with two options: 1 Serving to the left end of the serving field. 2 Serving to the right end of the serving field. Because there is no dominant strategy to serve exclusively in one of the two corners (the receiver would wait there and hit back the ball with ease), the server has to mix these two options. He will do that, so to make the receiver indifferent between both options (and vice versa). So, in equilibrium the win rates of making the point must be equal for both options available (H4).

Serving decisions from a game theoretic view The receiver tries to guess the serving direction. The server tries to avoid the direction expected. If the receiver guesses right, his chance of winning the point increases (and the server s decreases), and vice versa. The expected win rates of the server are noted. (The win rates of the receiver are 1 π) receiver left right left π LL π LR server right πrl π RR

Data Results amateurs Results professionals Comparison Data sets (data collection: Thomas Lehnert) Professionals: Swiss Indoors 2007, won by Roger Federer. 7 matches including one semifinal and the final. 787 serves (431 to the right, 356 to the left). Amateurs: 1 Verbandsliga I Berlin/Brandenburg Gruppe B, winter 2008. The winner is ranked about no. 500 in the DTB. 3 matches with 318 serves (192 to the right, 126 to the left) 2 USTA Championships Southern Division - NC, autumn 2007. One player is a tennis coach. 4 matches with 485 serves (252 to the left, 233 to the right).

Data Results amateurs Results professionals Comparison Amateur players serves won serves lost win rates χ 2 -test set score PLAYERS L R L R L R p-value 1. 2. 3. Teurer 15 23 13 23 53.6 50.0 0.766 6 2 7 Leickhoff 20 29 18 29 50.0 52.6 0.801 2 6 6 Kunkel 16 7 7 1 69.6 87.5 0.318 6 6 - Reckert 2 5 6 6 25.0 45.5 0.361 0 1 - Szabados 8 19 12 19 40.0 50.0 0.468 4 2 - Teurer 9 17 1 14 90.0 58.8 0.045 6 6 - Sandman 7 20 5 12 58.3 62.5 0.800 6 6 - Huggins 14 13 24 13 36.8 50.0 0.295 4 3 - Sutton 24 10 18 8 57.1 55.6 0.909 6 6 - Rincon 13 17 10 22 56.5 43.6 0.325 4 4 - Oxendine 13 22 11 6 54.2 78.6 0.061 6 6 - Ecos-Ossio 16 12 13 10 55.2 54.2 0.964 3 1 - Oxendine 21 28 17 20 55.3 58.3 0.775 3 6 - May 18 26 9 13 66.7 66.7 1.000 6 7 - overall 196 248 163 196 54.6 55.9 0.721 - - -

Data Results amateurs Results professionals Comparison Professional players PLAYERS serves won serves lost win rates χ 2 -test set score (rank no.) L R L R L R p-value 1. 2. 3. Blake (14) 19 17 2 3 90.5 85.0 0.592 6 6 - Hernandez (59) 13 16 4 16 76.5 50.0 0.073 3 4 - Wawrinka (36) 20 27 7 7 74.1 79.4 0.622 7 6 - Nalbandian (9) 19 19 9 11 67.7 63.3 0.717 6 2 - Mathieu (25) 17 15 7 4 70.8 79.0 0.545 6 6 - Dancevic (69) 12 17 18 12 40.0 58.6 0.153 3 1 - Federer (1) 21 16 5 9 80.8 64.0 0.180 6 6 - Del Potro (44) 4 13 6 13 40.0 50.0 0.590 1 4 - Mathieu (25) 24 17 13 13 64.9 56.7 0.493 2 6 - Baghdatis (16) 26 22 9 12 74.3 64.7 0.387 6 7 - Karlovic (22) 28 30 9 8 75.7 79.0 0.735 6 6 - Federer (1) 20 40 6 10 76.9 80.0 0.755 7 7 - Federer (1) 16 23 4 11 80.0 67.7 0.328 6 6 - Nieminen (27) 11 21 5 9 68.8 70.0 0.930 3 4 - overall 250 293 106 138 70.2 68.0 0.498 - - -

Data Results amateurs Results professionals Comparison Comparison of amateurs and professional players No apparent difference between amateur and professional players (H1): Only a few players fail in making their opponent indifferent in their choice of the side (H4). Overall, win rates on both sides are close to each other. This is the case, though the serving win rates of the amateurs are clearly lower than those of the professionals. Possibly, in competitive matches, win rate mixing is closer to optimal than in lopsided matches (H3).

Summary: Minimax play of amateurs Amateurs seem to be able to play Minimax in the field under real competitive conditions (H4). So, rationality, here seems to be - also - a property of the interaction, and not solely of the actors. Though, admittedly here the amateur players already are pretty experienced. (This is necessary to ensure that the observed serving direction is also the intended one.) the decision between two option is not too complex.

Serving as a test for Minimax decisions: Remaining problems There is only an indirect connection between successful serving and making the point. Any selection bias for the observed matches should be avoided. Modeling the quality of the players might lead to other equilibrium points, (too).

Beyond serving: Examples for interactions with mixed equilibria solutions The interaction structure can be found whenever the interest of the players are completely opposite to each other, e.g.: In a lot of sports and games. In interaction between a deviant and a controller (see Tsebelis 1990, Rauhut 2006) In interaction between a pursuer and an evader (,,Hide and Seek,,,Sherlock Holmes and,,prof. Moriarity in the,,final Adventure ). In warfare (,,Battle of the Bismarck Sea ).