ABSTRACT. Keywords: ecological-economic modeling, bycatch and discards, fishery management, incentivebased

Similar documents
Maximising net economic returns in mixed fisheries: how many species do we need to control?

The Southern and Eastern Scalefish and Shark Fishery (SESSF): history, management and lessons learnt

Harvest strategy policy and stock rebuilding for Commonwealth fisheries in Australia: Moving toward MEY. Peter Gooday

Measuring the Economic Performance of Australian Fisheries Management

Towards Ecosystem-Based Management Modelling Techniques 2. Whole Ecosystem Models

The South African and Namibian horse mackerel fisheries Prepared by Dave Japp and Melanie Smith. The South African horse mackerel

High seas: conservation and management measures to prevent significant adverse impacts on vulnerable marine ecosystems

Draft Discussion Document. May 27, 2016

3.4.3 Advice June Barents Sea and Norwegian Sea Cod in Subareas I and II (Norwegian coastal waters cod)

Sprat (Sprattus sprattus) in subdivisions (Baltic Sea)

7 GULF OF ALASKA POLLOCK

By far the majority of New Zealand s fisheries are performing well

Whiting (Merlangius merlangus) in divisions 7.b c and 7.e k (southern Celtic Seas and western English Channel)

Tasmanian Scalefish Fishery Code of Practice 2015

Management of the North Sea flatfish fishery: exploring alternative ITQ systems IIFET 2014, Brisbane, July 9 th 2014 K. G. Hamon, H. Bartelings, F.

ICES advises that when the MSY approach is applied, catches in 2019 should be no more than tonnes.

9.4.5 Advice September Widely distributed and migratory stocks Herring in the Northeast Atlantic (Norwegian spring-spawning herring)

Risk Assessments in the Pacific Fisheries for BC & Yukon

Management advisory for the Bay of Bengal hilsa fishery June 2012

Eastern Tuna and Billfish Fishery Sea Turtle Mitigation Plan (TMP)

Advice May Herring in Subdivisions and 32 (excluding Gulf of Riga herring)

By far the majority of New Zealand s fisheries are performing well

Modify Federal Regulations for Swordfish Trip Limits the Deep-set Tuna Longline Fishery. Decision Support Document November 2010

Fisheries Futures 2050 Bob Kearney, Barney Foran, Don Lowe, Franzi Poldy and Graham Turner

ICES WGCSE REPORT

Advice June 2012

Progress Made by Tuna Regional Fisheries Management Organizations (RFMOs)

Cod (Gadus morhua) in subdivisions 24 32, eastern Baltic stock (eastern Baltic Sea) *

Comparison of EU and US Fishery management Systems Ernesto Penas Principal Adviser DG Mare

Best Practice Guidance for Assessing the Financial Performance of Fishing Gear: Industry-led gear trials

By far the majority of New Zealand s fisheries are performing well

PORT PHILLIP BAY COMMERCIAL NETTING ADJUSTMENT PROGRAM. Information Booklet

Bycatch accounting and management in the Ross Sea toothfish fishery

Advice October 2012

Briefing on discards Definitions of discards

Advice June, revised September Herring in Division IIIa and Subdivisions (Western Baltic spring spawners)

Advice June Sole in Division IIIa and Subdivisions (Skagerrak, Kattegat, and the Belts)

Turning the tide for low impact fisheries. Ways to improve the CFP reform proposal

Saithe (Pollachius virens) in subareas 4 and 6, and in Division 3.a (North Sea, Rockall and West of Scotland, Skagerrak and Kattegat)

From right-based catch shares to benthic impacts

MEDIA RELEASE - 26 May 2015 Stormy Seas Ahead for Industrial Fishing after Factory Trawler Snubs Rec Fishers

Trawl fishery management of Eastern Arabian Sea

FISHERIES MANAGEMENT UNDER SPECIES ALTERNATION: CASE OF THE PACIFIC PURSE SEINER OFF JAPAN

DEPARTMENT OF CONSERVATION AND NATURAL RESOURCES FISHERIES BRANCH CENTRAL AGEING FACILITY REPORT TO DPFRG 33

Haddock (Melanogrammus aeglefinus) in divisions 7.b k (southern Celtic Seas and English Channel)

Advice June 2014

7. Catch Balancing. 7.1 Catch Balancing

9.4.5 Advice October Widely Distributed and Migratory Stocks Herring in the Northeast Atlantic (Norwegian spring-spawning herring)

OTHER SPECIES ANALYSIS 2007 ANDREW SMOKER NATIONAL MARINE FISHERIES SERVICE MARCH 2007

Mackerel (Scomber scombrus) in subareas 1 8 and 14, and in Division 9.a (the Northeast Atlantic and adjacent waters)

Whiting (Merlangius merlangus) in Division 6.a (West of Scotland)

Food Chain. Marine Food Webs and Fisheries

Management advisory for the Bay of Bengal Indian mackerel fishery

MAXIMUM ECONOMIC YIELD AND ITS IMPORTANCE IN FISHERIES MANAGEMENT

Evaluating Potential Fishery Effects of Changes to Other Species Management

Roundnose grenadier (Coryphaenoides rupestris) in Division 3.a (Skagerrak and Kattegat)

Herring (Clupea harengus) in subdivisions and 32 (central Baltic Sea, excluding Gulf of Riga)

92 ND MEETING DOCUMENT IATTC-92 INF-C

Comment on What Restoration Schemes Can Do. Or, Getting It Right Without Fisheries Transferable Quotas

ICES advice on fishing opportunities

Spurdog (Squalus acanthias) in the Northeast Atlantic

Atlantic Striped Bass Draft Addendum V. Atlantic Striped Bass Board May 9, 2017

Whiting (Merlangius merlangus) in Subarea 4 and Division 7.d (North Sea and eastern English Channel)

Assessment Summary Report Gulf of Mexico Red Snapper SEDAR 7

Economics, fisheries and responsible fisheries management

WORKING GROUP ON STOCK ASSESSMENTS 5 TH MEETING DOCUMENT SAR-5-08 TARGET SIZE FOR THE TUNA FLEET IN THE EASTERN PACIFIC OCEAN

8 TH MEETING DOCUMENT BYC-08 INF-A

STECF EXPERT WORKING GROUP EWG 18-09

What to do with Other Species, and some thoughts on meeting MSRA requirements in Alaska. overview

At Sea Simulation of the Landing Obligation on Irish Vessels

SEAFISH ECONOMIC ANALYSIS

A Model for Tuna-Fishery Policy Analysis: Combining System Dynamics and Game Theory Approach

Legislation. Lisa T. Ballance Marine Mammal Biology SIO 133 Spring 2013

Norway lobster (Nephrops norvegicus) in Division 4.a, Functional Unit 7 (northern North Sea, Fladen Ground)

Plaice (Pleuronectes platessa) in Division 7.e (western English Channel)

Greg Ardini. March 5, Final Draft

FISHERY ASSESSMENT REPORT TASMANIAN ROCK LOBSTER FISHERY 2010/11. Klaas Hartmann, Caleb Gardner and David Hobday

Please note: The present advice replaces the advice given in June 2017 for catches in 2018.

A Combined Recruitment Index for Demersal Juvenile Cod in NAFO Divisions 3K and 3L

This document is meant purely as a documentation tool and the institutions do not assume any liability for its contents

Structural Adjustment in Australia s South East Trawl Fishery. Frank Meere

The landings obligation in view of different management regimes

Prepared by Australia

Norway lobster (Nephrops norvegicus) in Division 4.a, Functional Unit 32 (northern North Sea, Norway Deep)

7 th Annual Meeting of the Commission January, The Hague, The Netherlands

Implications of reducing Norway lobster (Nephrops norvegicus) minimum size (MLS/MCRS) in the Skagerrak and Kattegat area (IIIa).

Albacore Tuna, South Pacific, Troll, Pole and Line

Sustainable Fisheries for Future Generations The Fisheries White Paper

Developments in managing small pelagic fisheries

Comprehensive Incentives for Reducing Chinook Salmon Bycatch in the Bering Sea Pollock Fleet: Individual Tradable Encounter Credits

FISHING ACTIVITY: SEABED TRAWLING

Atlantic cod, Norwegian Coastal cod, Gillnet

ALBACORE TUNA (ALB) INITIAL POSITION PAPER

R.P. Prabath K. JAYASINGHE National Aquatic Resources Research and Development Agency (NARA) Colombo 15 SRI LANKA

10.4 Advice May 2014

Sandeel (Ammodytes spp.) in Divisions IIIa, IVa, and IVb, SA 3 (Skagerrak and Kattegat, North and Central North Sea)

Structural adjustment in AUSTRALIAN FISHERIES

Fishing mortality in relation to highest yield. Fishing mortality in relation to agreed target

Undulate ray (Raja undulata) in divisions 8.a b (northern and central Bay of Biscay)

Keywords: Rights-Based Management, Fisheries, Voluntary, Experiment, Chignik

Transcription:

IIFET 21 Montpellier Proceedings ECOSYSTEM-WIDE IMPACTS OF ALTERNATIVE BYCATCH REDUCTION STRATEGIES: AN ECOLOGICAL-ECONOMIC ASSESSMENT OF THE AUSTRALIAN SOUTHERN AND EASTERN SCALEFISH AND SHARK FISHERY Trevor Hutton, CSIRO, trevor.hutton@csiro.au Olivier Thébaud, CSIRO, olivier.thebaud@csiro.au Beth Fulton, CSIRO, beth.fulton@csiro.au Sean Pascoe, CSIRO, sean.pascoe@csiro.au Soile Kulmala, CSIRO, soile.kulmala@csiro.au ABSTRACT A concern for the consequences of bycatch and discards in fisheries has led to the implementation of new policies and fisheries management plans aimed at their reduction in many fisheries around the world. Such plans have been developed for the Australian Commonwealth fisheries (the most recent bycatch action plan extends from 29 to 211 for this case study). These plans list a wide variety of species, including both commercial fish and non-commercial species, particularly those listed as threatened, endangered or protected. The paper presents an analysis of the potential economic and ecological impacts of alternative approaches to the implementation of these plans, with particular emphasis on the use of economic incentives. The analysis is centered on the Australian Commonwealth Southern and Eastern Scalefish and Shark Fishery, and is based on the Atlantis simulation model developed within CSIRO. Atlantis is a spatially explicit model with subcomponents that model the coupled physical transport-biogeochemical processes as elements of the ecosystem, as well as sub-models to include the fisheries, the annual assessments, and the implementation of management regulations and compliance. A feature of the Atlantis model is that it incorporates a fleet dynamics model that allows the main fleets to adjust their fishing behavior in response to incentives. Incentive-based bycatch management scenarios such as the use of deemed values within the existing trade-able quota scheme for over-quota landings, or the imposition of a tax on catches of threatened, endangered and protected species, are considered (as well as tradable bycatch quotas). The consequences of these scenarios are presented in terms of both ecological and economic impacts, with a focus on the ecosystem-wide implications of alternative regulations. Keywords: ecological-economic modeling, bycatch and discards, fishery management, incentivebased management INTRODUCTION Managing multi-stock, multi-fleet fisheries in order to reduce bycatch and discards is problematic due to the complex technical interactions which occur between fishing activities, where the selectivity of fishing gears does not match the differential productivity of fish stocks, and their temporal and spatial distribution. This is especially true for trawl gear, although gillnet and longline gear are also nonselective resulting in catches of rare species. Where fisheries are regulated through output controls (i.e. total allowable catches), discrepancies will usually be observed between the catch limitations and what is landed on deck. This leads to what is termed the catch-quota balancing problem (Sanchirico et al. 26) in quota regulated fisheries, where individual fishing operators will be confronted with a choice to land or discard fish caught in the process of fishing. The economic incentive to land or discard any given species is generally well recognized (e.g. Anderson 1994, Arnason 1994, Pascoe 1997). Bycatch (strictly, non-targeted catches) which have a positive expected commercial value, taking into account the opportunity costs of retaining and landing this catch (e.g. due to the uptake of holding capacity or processing time on-board fishing vessels) and the anticipated costs and benefits of exceeding individual catch allocations in quota-managed fisheries, will be landed as byproduct. Any non-targeted catch with zero commercial value (such as marine mammals), or the expected retaining and landing costs which are higher than the anticipated benefits, is expected to be discarded. 1

IIFET 21 Montpellier Proceedings In this study, the potential effectiveness of incentive based bycatch management is examined using the Atlantis ecosystem model of the Australian South East fishery (Fulton et al. 27). Management measures examined include deemed values (to allow over-quota landings and reduce discarding), bycatch quotas, and bycatch taxes. THE ATLANTIS MODEL OF THE SOUTH EAST AUSTRALIAN COMMONWEALTH FISHERIES The Southern and Eastern Scalefish and Shark Fishery (SESSF) is a complex multi-gear, multispecies fishery that covers a large proportion of Australian s Exclusive Economic Zone (Figure 1 left panel). It is Australia s largest scalefish fishery and provides most of the fresh fish to domestic markets, the two largest being in Sydney and Melbourne. The SESSF lands about 21 934 tonnes of fish which in 27/8 was worth about AUD$87 million (Morison et al. 29). The fishery has both trawl and non-trawl sectors (6 principle sectors that overlap in the stocks exploited and areas fished with the main sector being the Commonwealth Trawl Sector). Discarding in the SESSF occurs for a range of reasons, including lack of quota, high-grading, damage to fish, and weak markets for the landings of some species leading to low market prices (Liggins and Knuckey 1999, Ellison et al. 25). The mismatch between actual catches and quota holdings has also contributed to an increase in discarding since the introduction of ITQs in the trawl sector in 1989 (Baelde 21). Figure 1 - The area of the Southern and Eastern Scalefish and Shark Fishery (source AFMA Fishery Status Reports 27, AFMA (27))(left panel) and map of model domain covering same area (right panel)(source Fulton et al. 27). Atlantis is a spatially explicit ecosystem model that includes representation of ecological processes, fisheries, annual assessments and the implementation of management regulations (Fulton et al. 24, 25, 27). The physical environment is represented explicitly via a set of polygons matched to the major geographical and bioregional features of the simulated marine system. In the case study the geography of the region is represented by 71 polygonal boxes (Figure 1 right panel). The biological groups included are functional groups (that is, species with similar size, predators, diet, habitat preferences, life histories and migratory patterns) and the dominant target species in the Southeast Australian Commonwealth fisheries (Fulton et al. 27). The primary ecological processes in the model are consumption, production, waste production and cycling, migration, predation, recruitment, habitat dependency, and mortality (Fulton et al. 27). The model includes multiple fishing fleets, each with its own characteristics (regarding gear selectivity, habitat association, targeting, effort allocation and management structures). At its most complex it includes explicit handling of economic drivers, compliance decisions, exploratory fishing and other complicated processes such as quota trading (Fulton et al. 27). Based on targeting and gear use, all fisheries (including State fisheries) were grouped into fleets (depending on gear and catch profiles, that is, main target species). The main fleet components, for which a dynamic effort response was developed in SESSF Atlantis and the target and bycatch species included in the model are given in Table 1. 1 The commercial species of most concern are underlined, while iconic species such as seabirds, seals and whales are shown in italics. 2

IIFET 21 Montpellier Proceedings Table 1 - Main fleets in the model and their main target stocks and bycatch stocks (the species codes used in figures are listed, in parentheses). Fleet Target stocks Bycatch stocks Demersal fish trawl (dtrawlfd) Demersal flathead trawl (dtrawlfdb) Demersal celphalopod trawl (dtrawlcep) Demersal orange roughy trawl (dtrawlfdo) Prawn trawl (ptrawlpwn) Danish seine (dseinefdb) Midwater cephalopod trawl (midwccep) Midwater fish trawl (midwcfd) Demersal trawl for benthopelagics (dtrawlfbp) Demersal line for demersal fish (dlinefd) Demersal line for sharks (dlinesh) Demersal line for shallow water demersals (dlinefde) Demersal fish gillnet (netfd) Shark gillnet (netsh) Ling (FDC), Morwong (FPO), Cardinalfish (FVD), Gemfish (FVV), Whiting (FVO), dory/oreo/whiptail (FDD), Grenadier (FDE), Redfish (FDM), Ribaldo (FDP), Tiger flathead (FDB), Orange Roughy (FDO), Trevalla (FDF), School shark (SHR), Skates and rays (SSK), Blue warehou (SP), Gulper shark (REP) Morwong, Grenadier, Redfish,Tiger flathead, Squid Orange roughy, Ribaldo, Cardinalfish, Trevalla, School shark Prawns Tiger flathead, Morwong Squid, Ribaldo Cardinalfish, dory/oreo/whiptail, Ribaldo Morwong, Mackerel, Whiting, Grenadier Ling, dory/oreo/whiptail, Trevalla, Pelagic shark Gummy shark, demersal sharks, Dogfish, Pelagic shark Morwong, Grenadier, Redfish, Tiger flathead, Trevalla, Dogfish Ling, dory/oreo/whiptail, Trevalla Gummy shark, demersal sharks, Spotted warehou (FVB) Mackerel (FPL), Redbait (FBP), Gummy shark (SHB), demersal sharks (SHD), dogfish (SHC), seals (PIN), baleen whales (WHB), squid (CEP) Mackerel, Whiting, Trevalla, Gummy shark, demersal sharks, dogfish, School Shark, Skates and rays, Gulper shark, seals Cardinalfish, Gemfish, Whiting, Redbait, dory/oreo/whiptail, Tiger flathead, Ling, Trevalla, Gummy shark, Skates and rays, squid, seals, baleen whales Whiting, Redbait, dory/oreo/whiptail, Redfish, Tiger flathead, Ling, Gummy shark, demersal shark, Dogfish, Skates and rays, Blue warehou, squid Morwong, Cardinalfish, Gemfish, Whiting, Redbait, dory/oreo/whiptail, Grenadier, Tiger flathead, Ling, Orange roughy, Trevalla, Gummy shark demersal shark, pelagic shark, Squid, Skates and rays, Gulper shark, seals, sea-lions, orca Mackerel, Grenadier, Gummy shark, Skates and rays Morwong, Mackerel, Whiting, Redbait, Grenadier, Tiger flathead, School shark, Blue warehou Morwong, Mackerel, Whiting, Redbait, Tiger flathead, School shark, Blue warehou, Squid Tiger flathead, Ling, Gummy shark, demersal shark, Dogfish, Pelagic sharks, School sharks, Skates and rays, seabirds, seals, baleen whales Gulper shark, Whiting, Gummy shark, demersal sharks, Dogfish, Skates and rays, seabirds, baleen whales School sharks, Gulper sharks, seabirds Cardinalfish, dory/oreo/whiptail, Gummy shark, demersal shark, Skates and rays, Gulper shark, seabirds Cardinalfish, Spotted warehou, Whiting, Redbait, Orange roughy, Gummy shark, demersal shark, Skates and rays, Gulper shark, seabirds, sea-lions, seals, baleen whales, dolphins, orca Pelagic sharks, School sharks, Skates and rays, Blue warehou, Gulper shark, sea-lions, baleen whales, dolphins, orca In this version of the model, data for fleets size and estimates of biomass have been updated for a more recent time period (2-24) where possible. Year 2 is the reference year with 3

IIFET 21 Montpellier Proceedings historical fitting. From 21, the model runs dynamically without historical values applied to any of the variables in terms of the fleets. Economic incentives measures A review of potential incentive based bycatch options has been recently undertaken by Pascoe et al (21). Based on this review, three types of economic instruments aimed at reducing discards were identified as having potential applicability to the fishery: implementation of tradable individual bycatch quotas, introduction of taxes on catches of selected species, and application of deemed-value payments on over quota landings of commercial species. Bycatch quotas Quotas are applied to bycatch species (megafauna and rare species). In terms of seeking to lease or purchase in new quota, the quota trading equations specified in Fulton et al (27) are used with modifications such that a sub-fleet is only interested in looking to trade quota if its cumulative catch to a given date is greater than a trigger proportion of the quota (target and/or bycatch) in hand. Similarly a sub-fleet is only willing to trade out if it has a large excess that it does not expect to fill either as catch or bycatch. If a sub-fleet is willing to be in a trade, the difference between total take (cumulative catch and bycatch to date plus that expected for the rest of the year) for a species and the quota in hand is used to assess need (if take > quota) or if there is excess available for sale/lease (quota > take). In terms of scheduled effort, the expected spatial distribution of discards is also taken into account by the model, in that effort is allocated in locations that minimise expected exposure to bycatch and improve expected value per unit effort (thereby reducing the relative attractiveness of areas where there are potentially high catches of low value groups, which are more likely to be discarded due to high grading). This is implemented as an additional multiplier when computing effort distribution (see effort re-distribution functional relationships in Fulton et al. 27). Taxes Taxes can be applied to the take of species of concern (including bycatch for megafauna or rare species or over-quota catch in target species). Any taxes taken (i) reduce profit (acting as an additional cost term in the computation of total costs (see Fulton et al. 27)) and (ii) go to government tax revenue. In addition, during effort scheduling an incentive to minimise bycatch is introduced by including a cost term conditioned on expected exposure to bycatch: H e,s,i, j,m H bycatch,e,s,i, j,m R e,m,y, j = p s, j,m p tax,s, j,m s E h,i, j,m E h,i, j,m C E,i, j,m,y 1 i where Re, j,m,y is the expected return for sub-fleet j in month m of year y; p s, j, is the sale price of m species group s for that sub-fleet in that month; E h, i, j, is the historical effort expended in that month in m box i by the sub-fleet; H is the is the expected harvest of the group in box i in that month by that e, s, i, j, m p tax s, j, m sub-fleet (based on updating past catches per month);, is the bycatch tax for species group s for the sub-fleet in that month; H is the expected harvest of bycatch of the species group in bycatch, e, s, i, j, m that box in that month by that sub-fleet; andc is the total variable costs for that sub-fleet of E, i, j, m, y 1 fishing in box i in that month. Deemed values for quota species The calculation of the deemed values is based on a modified form of the market sale price (p s,m ) for fish being landed over and above the quota holding of a fleet for that species: ˆ = p s,m κ deem (when H s, i > Q s,i ) p deem, s, i, m where H s,i is the landed catch of species s by sub-fleet i and Q s,i is the corresponding quota. κ deem is the proportion of the price the government has set as the deemed value. The final deemed value payments made by sub-fleets go to the government as revenue (which is tracked explicitly). The effective 4

IIFET 21 Montpellier Proceedings market price (i.e. what the fisher gets) is the standard market price minus the deemed value for any landed catch H s, i > Q s,i. Scenarios In this paper, we present a sub-set of the simulation results obtained, for a selection of approaches to the use of economic instruments to reduce bycatch and discards. Bycatch quotas and taxes were applied to species such as seals as they are listed in the Bycatch and Discard Workplan (AFMA 29) as high risk (Table 2). Deemed values were applied to over-quota catches for stocks such as Tiger Flathead, Morwong, and School Whiting (Table 2), essentially key species for which the TAC is restrictive. Table 2 - The scenarios run in the analysis of incentives to reduce bycatch and discarding Base run Scenario name Assumption Values set values Scenario No. 1 2 3 RESULTS Bycatch quota (megafauna) Tax (megafauna) Deemed value (8 companion stocks) Whales, dolphins and seals Tax on whales, dolphins and seals Deemed values on Tiger flathead, Ling, Morwong, Blue grenadier, Spotted Warehou, Blue Warehou, Blue-eye Trevalla, School whiting No restriction $/kg $/kg Approximately.5 of previous incidental catch, that is Whales (WHB): 7 tonnes limit on shark net fisheries. Dolphins (WHS) 75kg limit on seine fleet and 25kg limit on shark net fleet. Seals reduction in incidental catch restriction by.5 for all fleets that incidentally capture seals. Whales ($1/kg; Dolphins $5/kg an seals $1/kg).5*price per kg/stock Overall model distribution of catches across a range of stocks relates well to the observed distribution and most importantly captures the relative differential retention rates across species (Figure 2). In total tonnage, the largest landings are taken by the main demersal trawl fleets (e.g. dtrawlfd) and include catches of species such as Blue Grenadier. The major discarding fleets in the model are trawl fleets (dtrawlfd and dtrawlfdo), a Danish seine fleet (dseinefdb), and to a lesser extent a net fleet (netsh) and a line fleet (dlinefde). 1 9 8 Landings per species (Tonnes) 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 Observed landings Modelled landings Gemfish Spotted Warehou Blue Warehou School Whiting Dory Blue Grenadier Morwong Ling Tiger Flathead Orange Roughy Blue-eye Trevalla Ribaldo Redfish Figure 2 - Model estimated and observed landings for key species groups in the model (base year = 2) Dem. Shark Deepwater Dogfish Gummy Shark Pelagic Shark School Shark Gulper Shark Redbait Small Demersal Prawns 5

IIFET 21 Montpellier Proceedings Scenario 1 - Bycatch Quota on megafauna (whales, dolphins, and seals) The introduction of a Bycatch Quota on whales and dolphins entails an immediate decrease of discarding of whales in the order of 27 tonnes, whereas for dolphins it is in the region of.7 tonnes (Figure 3a). The estimate for seals is lower, with a value of.5 tonnes. These reductions correspond to a reduction of the bycatch and discarding by respectively 1%, 29.1% and 88% for whales, dolphins and seals in year 2.. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1 11 12. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1 11 12 Change in Discards of Whales (WHB) in Tonnes -5. -1. -15. -2. -25. -3. -.1 -.2 -.3 -.4 -.5 -.6 -.7 -.8 Change in Discards of Seals (PIN) and Dolphins (WHS) in Tonnes Change in Catch of NetSH fleet (Tonnes) -5-1 -15-2 -25 Sum of WHB Sum of WHS Sum of PIN -3 a Sum of WHB Sum of FVS Sum of FVB Sum of FDS Sum of FDF Sum of SHB Sum of SHD Sum of SHP Sum of SHR Sum of SSK Sum of SP b Figure 3 - Changes in a) discards of whales (WHB), dolphins (WHS) and seals (PIN) and b) catch of key species by NetSH fleet The implications of this reduction in the catch 2 of whales at a fishery level are significant. The shark net fleet (netsh) which is the main fleet catching whales is constrained by the bycatch quota on marine mammals. This entails a reduction in its discards of other species and in its overall catches of these species, as illustrated in Figure 3b. The main species that are caught in lower numbers by netsh are the shark species (School shark, Gummy shark and Pelagic shark). Fish species that are also caught in lower numbers are Spotted and Blue Warehou. Given that the fleets that incidentally catch marine mammals are limited in number, and that the initial allocation of bycatch quotas for these species is based on the reference catch levels in the fishery, no trade opportunities exist that would allow the netsh fleet to relax this new constraint on its activity, by leasing in quota from other, less constrained fleets. Hence, the bycatch quota scenario performs in this case similarly to what would occur under an individual nontransferable quota for the catch of marine mammals. This reduction in activity and catches leads this fleet to increase the proportion of its quota allocations that it leases out to other fleets, thus leading to cascading effects throughout the fleets, notably to changes in their fishing effort, due to the cumulative effects of fleet responses in terms of quota trading, targeting and effort determinants (Figure 4 left panel). The two main fleets affected are the shark net fleet (netsh) and the demersal trawl fleet (dtrawlfd), which both reduce their fishing effort as a result of the management measure. The model allows one to assess the overall consequences of the management measure on the economic performance of the fleets. As illustrated in Figure 4 (right panel), economic profits in the trawl fisheries decreases with the adoption of the management measure, as these fleets are negatively impacted after the implementation of the bycatch quota. The observed reduction in fishing effort in the shark net fleet (netsh) however does not reduce the level of economic profit in this fleet, rather increases in profitability after the adoption of the management measure are observed, possibly as a result of having retained sufficient catch while fishing to cover onshore costs, while not suffering the costs of fishing longer through the year. This outcome is at least in part a reflection of the marginal economic position the shark fleet was in during the late 199s and 2 the period used to parameterize the cost model, and the fact that non-economic drivers (lifestyle fishing) are also influencing participation in this fleet. 6

IIFET 21 Montpellier Proceedings 2 $4 $2 dlinefd Change in effort per fleet (boat-days) -2-4 -6-8 -1-12 Sum of dtrawlfdb Sum of ptrawlpwn Sum of netsh Sum of dtrawlfd Sum of dseinefdb Sum of dtrawlfdo Sum of netfd Sum of dtrawlcep Sum of dlinefd Sum of dtrawlfbp Change in net rent per fleet (Million $ AUD) $ -$2 -$4 -$6 -$8 -$1 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1 11 12 dlinefde dlinesh dseinefdb dtrawlcep dtrawlfbp dtrawlfd dtrawlfdb dtrawlfdo midwccep midwcfd netfd netsh -14 -$12 ptrawlpwn -16 -$14 Figure 4 - Change in effort (left panel) and economic profit (right panel) per fleet Overall, fleet responses lead to wide ranging modifications in their catches and uptake of quota for various species. The reduction in catches is associated with decreases in landings of many species. The scenario leads to an increase in the discards of two stocks as compared to the base run, namely Blue Grenadier and Tiger Flathead, but small increases in discards are also observed for Blue-eye Trevalla (Figure 5). For other species, decreases in discards are observed, notably Spotted Warehou, Ling, Gummy Shark, School shark and Redbait (Figure 5). The decrease in the discarding across the range of these stocks reflects lower effort and thus fishing mortality by the fleets that traditionally target these stocks. 15 1 5 Changes in discards (Tonnes) -5-1 -15 years 2-6 years 7-12 -2-25 Figure 5 - Change in total discards per species Scenario 2 - Tax on megafauna (whales, dolphins, and seals) The changes in the discarding of marine mammals associated with this scenario are illustrated in Figure 6a. The tax on catches of marine mammals results in an immediate decrease of discarding of whales in the order of 15 tonnes which steadily increases to just over 2 tonnes (a 55.5% and 74% decrease, respectively). For dolphins the impact of the tax is relatively large compared to the base run incidental catch of these animals, with discards decreasing by 6kg (a 75.4% decrease)(with the effect lessening slightly in the longer run). The estimate for seals is lower in absolute terms, with a change in discarding levels of.5 tonnes which equates to an average decline in discarding average over years 2-12 of 53.6%. As was the case with bycatch quota, these decreases in discarding reflect actual decreases in incidental catch as fleets avoid the bycatch of these animals. As in the previous scenario, the model shows that the implications of this reduction in the catches of marine mammals are significant at a fishery level, and result both directly and indirectly from the impact which the taxes have on the shark net (netsh) fleet as well as the other fleets that have incidental catch of whales, dolphins and seals. The shark net fleet (netsh), which is the main fleet that incidentally catches whales (and which in this scenario experiences the largest decrease in incidental catch due to taxes), decreases its effort as a result. This entails a reduction in its catches of other species, as illustrated in Figure 6b. The main species that are caught in lower numbers are the main target species of this fleet: the shark species (i.e. School shark, Gummy shark and Pelagic shark), although Spotted Warehou, Blue Warehou and small demersals are also caught in lower numbers 7

IIFET 21 Montpellier Proceedings.1 5 Change in Discards of Seals (PIN) & Dolphins (WHS) in Tonnes. -.1 -.2 -.3 -.4 -.5 -.6 -.7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1 11 12 Sum of WHS Sum of PIN Sum of WHB -5-1 -15-2 -25 Change in Discards of Whales (WHB) in Tonnes a Change in Total Catch (Tonnes) -5-1 -15-2 -25 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1 11 12 Sum of FVB Sum of FDS Sum of SHB Sum of SHP Sum of SHR Sum of SP Figure 6 - Changes in a) discards of whales (WHB), dolphins (WHS) and seals (PIN) and b) catch by NetSH fleet b These impacts induce the fleets to modify their activity profiles (and reduce effort), which in turn affects their uptake of quota for various species, reducing their catch, landings and discards. Figure 7 (left panel) shows the response in terms of fishing effort for the main fleets in which impacts have been observed in the simulation. The main fleets that are affected are the netsh, the demersal fish trawl (dtrawlfd) and the dtrawlfdb fleets (Figure 7 - left panel). Again, the main demersal trawl fleet (dtrawlfd) is negatively affected to a considerable degree as it too catches marine mammals which it cannot avoid and as such the tax becomes restrictive in terms of its operations. All of the fleets show in Figure 7 which are negatively impacted (i.e. decline in activity) incidentally catch marine mammals. Note the demersal trawl fleet for Orange roughy displays positive effects which are indirect (as in the model it is assumed it does not interact with marine mammals). The model allows one to assess the overall consequences of the management measure on the economic performance of the fleets. As illustrated in Figure 7 (right panel), economic profits in some of the trawl fisheries decreases following adoption of the management measure, as these fleets are initially negatively impacted from the implementation of the tax. However, the impact on economic profit of the main affected fleet fluctuates over the time period of the model run, as the dynamic adjustments in fishing tactics take place. This leads to years in which some positive changes in rent are also observed for the general demersal trawl fleet (dtrawlfd). For two of the trawl fleets (dtrawlfdo and dtrawlfdb) indirect effects of the management measure lead to positive, but limited profitability increases. As in the bycatch quota scenario the reduction in effort of the shark net fleet (netsh) leads to improved economic performance and increases in economic profits compared to the base run. 2 3 Change in Effort (boat-days) -2-4 -6-8 -1-12 -14 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1 11 12 Change in net rent per fleet (Million $ AUD) 2 1-1 -2-3 -4 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1 11 12 Sum of dtrawlcep Sum of dtrawlfd Sum of dtrawlfdb Sum of dtrawlfdo Sum of dlinefd Sum of netsh Figure 7 - Change in effort (left panel) and economic profits (right panel) per fleet In this scenario as in the previous, discards increase as compared to the base run for Blue Grenadier and Tiger Flathead. For other species, decreases in discards are observed, the largest decreases being for School shark and Ling (species mostly previously landed by the shark net fleet -5 dtrawlcep dtrawlfd dtrawlfdb dtrawlfdo dlinefde netsh 8

IIFET 21 Montpellier Proceedings (netsh)), these being all an indirect consequence of the adoption of a tax on the bycatch of marine mammals (Figure 8). 1 5 Changes in discards (Tonnes) -5-1 years 2-6 years 7-12 -15-2 Figure 8 - Change in total discards per species Scenario 3 - Deemed value (3 companion stocks) As was the case with the previous scenarios, the simulation illustrates the magnitude of the impact on the stocks across the fisheries and fleets. In this scenario there are large declines in the catch and landings for the main target species; however the impact on the discards are not as clear as before. The change in discards between the base run and the deemed value scenario are presented in Figure 9. For this scenario there are considerable increases in discarding, the most being for Redbait, Blue Grenadier and Tiger Flathead. However, for other species the opposite occurs in that, discarding decreases, this being the case for Small demersals, Gummy shark, Skates and rays, School shark, and Morwong. 25 2 15 Changes in discards (Tonnes) 1 5 years 2-6 years 7-12 -5-1 -15 Figure 9 - Change in total discards per species Ascertaining the exact direction of change for each of the main stocks, that is what combination of change in discarding and landings it experiences, can be interpolated from (Figure 1). The right panel shows the area within the red square in the left panel in more detail. The red line in the right panel represents constant fishing mortality while all points above correspond to an increase in fishing mortality with the scenario, while the opposite is true below the line. Where quota really is constraining (as is the case for species such as Morwong) then providing even the smallest deemed value for these species is sufficient to induce increases in landings. For instance, the direction Morwong is moving in is what is expected from the introduction of a deemed value, in that more fish of this species are landed and fewer are discarded. The large decreases in landings of Redbait and Blue Grenadier are possibly due to a reduction in targeting of these stocks as fleets shift fishing practices in response to the introduction of deemed values. Overall, the effect on effort is such that effort mostly declines, especially in the case of the Danish Seine fleet, the demersal trawlers and the prawn trawlers (Figure 11 left panel). The reasons for the large decline in Danish Seine is probably related to avoidance behaviour as they do not land over-quota (nor pay deem values) and their economic profits are mostly unaffected. For the demersal trawlers targeting Tiger Flathead (dtrawlfdb) effort fluctuates within the region of zero change, as for the shark net fleet 9

IIFET 21 Montpellier Proceedings (netsh)(figure 11 left panel). The year to year variability in effort grows for some sectors (in particular the general demersal trawl fleet, dtrawlfd). 25 25 Blue Grenadier Redbait 2 15 2 15 1 1 5 Pelagic Shark 5 Orange Spotted Roughy Ling Warehou School Whiting Tiger Flathead Blue-eye Dory Dem. Pelagic Gemfish Ribaldo Shark Shark Gulper Deepwater Trevalla Warehou SharkDogfish -4-35 -3-25 -2-15 -1-5 Redfish Morwong 5 1 School Shark Dem. Shark Ribaldo -25-2 -15-1 -5 Gulper Shark5 1 15 2 25 Gemfish Dory Blue Warehou Blue-eye Trevalla -5 Deepwater Dogfish -1-5 Gummy Shark Redfish -15 Morwong -1-2 -15 Figure 1 - Changes in landings (x axis, in tonnes) and discards (y axis, in tonnes) (the right panel shows the area within the red square in the left panel in more detail). -25 1 2 Change in Effort (boat-days) -1-2 -3-4 -5-6 -7-8 -9 Figure 11 - Change in effort (left panel) and economic profits (right panel) per fleet The impacts on the economics of the fleets are illustrated in Figure 11 (right panel). Amongst the most affected fleets, the demersal trawl fleet targeting Orange roughy has a slight decrease in economic profits in the second year (associated with deemed value payments); however this is temporary as the fleet avoids bycatch of the deemed value species after the first year. The demersal trawl fleet s (dtrawlfd) economic profits decreases sharply after the introduction of deemed values (Figure 11 right panel). This is due to deemed value payments made, quota trading costs and the indirect effects of these measures on the fleet, and to the fact that the fleet is not able to avoid the deemed value species. The demersal line fleet targeting Blue grenadier (dlinefde) reduces its fishing effort and it makes deemed value payments. However, this does not affect its profitability overall (Figure 11 right panel) which implies that their economic performance has improved compared to the base run, excluding the effects of deemed value payments. DISCUSSION 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1 11 12 Sum of dtrawlfd Sum of dtrawlfdb Sum of dtrawlfdo Sum of netsh Sum of dseinefdb Sum of dlinefde Sum of ptrawlpwn The results presented from this version of the SESSF Atlantis have been based on a calibration of the model to historical data for the fishery, and using simple scenarios that evaluate the adoption of incentive based bycatch management measures. The results illustrate the high degree of complexity which arises from the interaction of ecological changes and fishing fleet dynamics (through effort allocation, quota trading and investment decisions) in response to management intervention in a mixed fishery. Overall, all the scenarios lead to a more or less transitional reduction in fishing activity, catches and landings, and to somewhat contrasted impacts with respect to bycatch and discards. Change in net rent per fleet (Million $ AUD) -2-4 -6-8 -1-12 -14-16 -18 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1 11 12 dtrawlfd dtrawlfdb dtrawlfdo netsh dseinefdb dlinefde ptrawlpwn 1

IIFET 21 Montpellier Proceedings When bycatch quotas are applied to species of conservation concern (e.g. megafauna such as whales, dolphins and seals), the quotas pose a minimal incentive to avoid areas where these species occur since, historically, there has been relative little contact with these animals. Incidents have occurred, but the chance of individual vessels making contact are so low that fleets see little reason (during their effort allocation decisions) to avoid potentially sensitive areas. For cases where the species were caught by a few fleets only, the initial allocation of catch shares, which are defined as a proportion of historical incidental catches/encounters, means that the opportunities for trading quota for these species are fairly limited. Hence the quotas impact the fleets in a similar way as non-tradable individual quotas would have, constraining fleets at reduced levels of effort and catch. For similar reasons, the introduction of a tax on the catch of on these same species leads to initial reductions in the fishing activity of the fleets directly impacted, with only slow adjustments in fishing strategies taking place over longer periods of time. With the rate of contact being low, the anticipated (and potential) tax payments seem to have little impact on original decision making in fleets. However, given the size of the animals that are of conservation concern (e.g. whales) when contact is made with them the financial burden can be quite crippling, effectively closing down operations for that fishing vessel. For the deemed values, which are aimed at commercial species and quota species in particular, the behavioural response amongst the fleets is almost as if the deemed value acted as an on-off switch effect in this version of the model. Where quota really is constraining (which it is not the case for a number species, except for species such as Morwong) then providing even the smallest deemed value for these species is sufficient to induce increases in landings. In these circumstances, increasing the value for the deemed values does not further modify the behaviour. If higher deemed values were used, then high-grading behaviour occurs, leading to species being discarded regardless of the removal of the quota constraint. This is, for example, the case for the Danish seine fishery, particularly when it is assumed that they base discarding decisions on market information at the start of each trip. Comparing across incentive measures, while deemed values are separate as they only relate to commercial species (essentially to allow over-quota uptake at a cost), the bycatch quotas and taxes are applied to the same species groups in order to allow for a comparison. The bycatch quota is relatively more effective largely due to the fact that there are limited trading opportunities and the quota levels chosen in the scenarios are very restrictive, as compared to the financial penalties of a tax. This, of course, assumes compliance with the regulations. Further simulations should allow the determination of the tax rates that entails impacts equivalent to a given level of quota constraint. This research represents a first test-case application of an ecosystem model that includes fleet behaviour, to model the potential effects of various incentive based approaches to the reduction of bycatch and discards in a mixed fishery. The results herein should be considered tentative, as the detailed sequence of direct and indirect effects that impact on the fleets (and their catches and discards) via a cascade of complex linkages still require a full exploration and some clarification in terms of processes. Further work will focus on determining the relative contribution of the different behavioural responses of the fleets (in terms of effort allocation, quota trading, species targeting, etc.) to the overall impacts observed from the implementation of a given measure. ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS This study was undertaken as part of the AFMA funded project Use of incentives to manage fisheries bycatch. REFERENCES AFMA 29. South East Trawl Fishery (Board Trawl and Danish Seine): Bycatch and Discarding Workplan. 1 July, 29 to 3 June, 211. Australian Fisheries Management Authority. Anderson, Lee G., 1994, A note on the economics of discards, Marine Resource Economics 9, pp 183-186. Arnason, R. 1994. On catch discarding in fisheries, Marine Resource Economics, 9, pp 189-27. 11

IIFET 21 Montpellier Proceedings Baelde, P. 21. Fishers description of changes in fishing gear and fishing practices in the Australian South East Trawl Fishery. Mar. Freshwater Res., 52: 411-17. Elliston, L., T. Kompas, and C, Bosch 25. Discarding of commercial catch: Implications for Commonwealth fisheries managed with ITQs. abare ereport 5.8. Prepared for the Fisheries Resources Research Fund, Canberra. Fulton, E.A., M. Fuller, A.D.M. Smith, A. Punt 24. Ecological Indicators of the Effects of fishing Final Report. R99/1546. Australian Fisheries Management Authority. 24pp. Fulton, E. A., Smith, A. D. M., and Punt, A. E. 25. Which ecological indicators can robustly detect effects of fishing? ICES Journal of Marine Science, 62: 54-551. Fulton, E.A., Smith, A.D.M., Smith, D.C., 27. Alternative management strategies for Southeastern Australian Commonwealth Fisheries: Stage 2: Quantitative Management Strategy Evaluation. Report to the Australian Fisheries Management Authority and the Fisheries Research and Development Corporation. CSIRO Marine and Atmospheric Research, 4 p. Liggins, G.W. and I.A. Knuckey 1999. Factors discarding in the South East Fishery implications for stock assessment and bycatch reduction. In: C.D. Buxton and S.E. Eayrs (Eds.), Establishing meaningful targets for bycatch reduction in Australian fisheries. Australian Society for Fish Biology Workshop Proceedings, Hobart September 1998. Australian Society for Fish Biology, Canberra, 56-71pp. Morison, A., H. Patterson and S. Vieira 29. Southern and Eastern Scalefish and Shark Fishery overview. In: Fishery Status Reports 28. Status of Fish Stocks and Fisheries Managed by the Australian Government. D. Wilson, R. Curtotti, G. Begg and K. Phillips (Eds.). Bureau of Rural Sciences & Australian Bureau of Agricultural and Resource Economics, Canberra. Pascoe, S. 1997. Bycatch management and the economics of discarding. FAO Fisheries Technical Paper 37. Pascoe, S., J. Innes, D. Holland, M. Fina, O. Thébaud, R. Townsend, J. Sanchirico, R. Arnason, C. Wilcox, T. Hutton 21. Use of incentive based management systems to limit bycatch and discarding, International Review of Environmental and Resource Economics [in press]. Sanchirico, J.N., D. Holland, K. Quigley and M. Fina 26. Catch-quota balancing in multi-species individual fishing quotas. Marine Policy 3: 767-785. 1 There are 16 additional non-dynamic fleets in the model apart from those listed in the table (see Fulton et al. 27) 2 In this paper, the term catch refers to what is caught by the gear, whereas landings are the portion of the catch that is returned to the port. 12