Paying to keep whales A case study of biodiversity protection

Similar documents
Gallup on Public Attitudes to Whales and Whaling

Report No. 27 to the Storting

Class Notes 4: Endangered Species

Re: Consultation on the addition of narwhal and two bowhead whale populations to the SARA List

ALBERTA WILDERNESS ASSOCIATION. Hunting, Trapping, and Fishing

International Fund for Animal Welfare. Research on Attitudes toward Commercial Whaling. Conducted by: Benenson Strategy Group April 2012

Section 3: The Future of Biodiversity

CONVENTION ON INTERNATIONAL TRADE IN ENDANGERED SPECIES OF WILD FAUNA AND FLORA

The Salmon Industry: Twenty-Five Predictions for the Future

What is Bushmeat? Bushmeat refers to all wildlife species used for meat, including threatened and endangered species

The Growth and Socioeconomic Value of the Whale Watch Industry Worldwide. Mick McIntyre, Asia Pacific Director

Whales have been hunted for centuries

A new vision for the Birds Directive & The Positive Role of Hunting

Electronic Monitoring of Norwegian Minke Whaling

Why has the cod stock recovered in the North Sea?

October Net Loss: Overfishing Off the Pacific Coast

OCEAN2012 Transforming European Fisheries

Breaking The Brand. Conservation - A New Approach. International Zoo News Vol. 62. No. 3 (2015), pp

Endangered Wildlife Trust Position Statement on Legalising the International Trade In Rhino Horn

Overfishing Atlantic Bluefin Tuna

Position of WWF Mongolia Program Office on current situation of Argali hunting and conservation in Mongolia

environmentaldefender s office ltd new south wales

Cariboo-Chilcotin (Region 5) Mule Deer: Frequently Asked Questions

Sharks: We re not just talking great whites. There are around 500 known species of shark. Dive for Sharks

Progress Made by Tuna Regional Fisheries Management Organizations (RFMOs)

FCE READING SPECIES. Which endangered species: has had its products replaced by other products? 0: B. is sometimes killed for entertainment?

Wild caught sustainable seafood

Whales are warm-blooded mammals that live in the sea, breathe air, and nurse their young with mother's milk. They are often called marine mammals

BLUE, FIN AND SEI WHALE RECOVERY PLAN

Charting a Course to Sustainable Fisheries Summary

IUCN Guidelines for THOPHY HUNTING to promote conservation. Sandro Lovari

Legislation. Lisa T. Ballance Marine Mammal Biology SIO 133 Spring 2013

WWF POSITION STATEMENT 12th Meeting of the Conference of the Parties to CITES Santiago, 3-15 November 2002

Annual Report of the International Whaling Commission nd Annual Meeting, 2000

WHALES. & Whale Sharks

Silencing The Uproar

Tuesday 3 June 2014 Morning

Time to refocus A constructive vision for the evolution and future of the International Whaling Commission as a cetacean protection organisation

By-Catch and Discard Management: The Key to Achieving Responsible and Sustainable Fisheries in Europe

Proposal for cooperation between GRASP and the CMS Gorilla Agreement

SUSTAINABILITY F.A.Q

A SURVEY ON MOOSE MANAGEMENT IN CENTRAL ONTARIO

Statement of the World Forum of Fisher People To the FAO Conference on Small Scale Fisheries, Bangkok, 2008

FISHERIES CO-OPERATION ICELAND AND NORWAY WITH. Presented by Philip Rodgers ERINSHORE ECONOMICS

NZ Sport Fishing Council submission on the proposal for an inseason increase to the total allowable catch for southern bluefin tuna

Healthy Planet. legacy circle

Genetically modified salmon is fit for the table

Tigers to be freed. News Story Original Version. schoolsonline.britishcouncil.org. 20th April 2015

OCEAN2012 Fish Dependence Day - UK

Whale science and how (not) to use it

ATLANTIC STURGEON. Consultations on listing under the Species at Risk Act

Threats to Biodiversity/Sustainability

CCAMLR MPA Edited June 2017

Testimony of Ray Hilborn to U.S. Senate subcommittee.

WHALES KILLED IN ROSS SEA MARINE PROTECTED AREA

Save the Whales: Reloaded forms new global community

Effective Collaboration Between Scientists, Managers and Policy Makers

COUNCIL DIRECTIVE 79/409/EC. of 2 April on the conservation of the wild birds

Feeding fish to fish is this a responsible practice?

WILDLIFE AND COUNTRYSIDE LINK BRIEFING KEY ISSUES FOR THE 61 ST MEETING OF THE INTERNATIONAL WHALING COMMISSION. May 2009 TO THE UK GOVERNMENT:

Tyler Kuhn Yukon Department of Environment P.O. Box 2703 Whitehorse YT Y1A 2C6 Canada

Japan s report on Paragraph 13, CMM

Lessons to be learnt from Mekong River for Asia

Management options for the southern bluefin tuna (STN 1) fishery

Australian Churches Gambling Taskforce

As the Fur Free Alliance we urge the Czech Republic to commit itself to a Europe that values animal welfare and make an end to fur farming.

2018 COM Doc. No. PA4_810 / 2018 November 7, 2018 (11:44 AM)

Original language: English CoP17 Doc CONVENTION ON INTERNATIONAL TRADE IN ENDANGERED SPECIES OF WILD FAUNA AND FLORA

Regional workshop on the implementation of the CITES shark and ray listings, Dakar, August 2014 Page 1

Nordatlantisk Fiskeriministerkonference i Shediac 29. august 2017

Chapter 14. Wildlife, Fisheries and Endangered Species. What are we Saving? Traditional Single-Species Wildlife Management

FINAL ENVIRONMENTAL IMPACT STATEMENT ON RESIDENT CANADA GOOSE MANAGEMENT Questions and Answers

Controlled Take (Special Status Game Mammal Chapter)

Canadian Attitudes towards Seal Hunting Basic Attitudes

Fishery. Fishing vessels (Dept. of Finance)

Conservation for a blue planet:

Sustainable initiative: Northern bluefin tuna

CHAPTER 8 UNINTENDED CONSEQUENCES OF TRADE IN RHINO HORN ON RHINO RANGE STATES: A KENYAN PERSPECTIVE AUTHOR BENSON OKITA, KENYA WILDLIFE SERVICE

BREAKING RANKS Denmark goes it alone on whaling policy An analysis by Dr. Sandra Altherr and Jennifer Lonsdale

FORMERLY THE NATIONAL COALITION FOR MARINE CONSERVATION (NCMC) Billfish Conservation Act Implementing Regulations; NOAA-NMFS

Horn of Contention

to provide for the proper conservation of whale stocks and thus make possible the orderly development of the whaling industry

IN THE FEDERAL COURT OF AUSTRALIA NEW SOUTH WALES DISTRICT REGISTRY No. NSD 995 / 2005 HUMANE SOCIETY INTERNATIONAL INC SUMMARY OF RELEVANT FACTS

Winter 2015/ Halibut & Blackcod Market Bulletin

Inquiry into trade in elephant ivory and rhino horn Submission

Animals Kept in Zoos: There are not many people in the world who haven t visited a zoo or safari park in their lifetime.

News English.com Ready-to-use ESL / EFL Lessons NZ tells Japan s whalers to stay at home

The Impacts of Policy and Macroeconomic Conditions on Horse Markets

To: Mr Hugo-Maria Schally Head of Unit - Global Sustainability, Trade and Multilateral Agreements DG Environment European Commission

SB194 3/13/2017 EXHIBIT C Senate Committee oncommerce Labor and Energy Date: Total pages: 18 Exhibit begins with: C1 thru C18

Biodiversity and Conservation Biology

Tonga Case Study - Taki Hausia & Olive Andrews

AmericAn PlAice. consultations on listing under the Species at Risk Act

Independent Economic Analysis Board. Review of the Estimated Economic Impacts of Salmon Fishing in Idaho. Task Number 99

Tuesday 7 June 2016 Morning

National Report on Large Whale Entanglements

Secretary Game Animal Panel PO Box 9134 Addington CHRISTCHURCH 8243

Global Industry Perspective Greg Tyler, Vice President of Marketing USA Poultry & Egg Export Council

The Aftermath of Global Financial Crises

Submission on summary of the Draft Convention on Biological Diversity National Report

Transcription:

Paying to keep whales A case study of biodiversity protection Noel Castree Can threatened resources be protected by consumer power rather than legislation? A recent idea suggests that, if enough consumers believe certain resources are worthy of protection, those resources can pay for their own survival. This article describes a recent proposal to price the right of whales to live, and assesses its prospects for success. The case study is relevant to A-level topics that cover biodiversity under threat, sustainability and resource consumption Should valuable natural resources pay for their right to survive on the planet? This may seem a strange question, but many environmental policy makers believe that they should. This article explores a new scheme designed to protect whale species from harvesting for human consumption or scientific research. The scheme aims to harness the market power of consumers who are willing to pay for whales not to be caught. To understand why the scheme has been devised we need to look at recent attempts to reduce the global catch of whales, and why they have been ineffective. Why are whales still being caught? Whales are iconic mammals. People all over the world marvel at their beauty and their size (most whales are large). They are familiar to us we see them in wildlife documentaries and in aquariums, and people will pay a lot of money to watch them swim in the wild. But not everybody values whales in this way. In some cultures the consumption of whale meat (and blubber) is normal practice. For these people, killing whales is acceptable in an ethical sense. They are happy to spend part of their income on purchasing whale meat to eat. 22 Geography Review

alive? Glossary Cap and trade scheme An environmental policy that places a limit on the amount a natural resource can be used, specifies legitimate resource users, divides this amount up into shares per user, and allows users to sell their shares if they do not wish to use them directly. Environmental bads Elements of the non-human world that, naturally or because of human activity, affect people negatively. Environmental goods Those elements of the non-human world that people value for practical, moral or aesthetic reasons. Box 1 Has there been a real decline in whaling? Tables 1 and 2 on p. 24 indicate that there s been an appreciable decline in global whale harvest since the mid-1980s. However, the decline is less than it seems because whaling nations, anticipating the ban, over-harvested in the 2 years leading up to it. Since the ban, total whale catches have declined for many species, but in part this reflects the lack of mature whales available due to the earlier overharvesting. Meanwhile, some species are still subject to high harvest rates. Antiwhalers want to eliminate commercial whaling altogether and hence consider the ban only partly effective. In the mid-1970s the radical environmental organisation Greenpeace launched a save the whales campaign. This brought the differences between anti- and pro-whaling arguments into sharp relief. Forty years on the debate still rages and there is no resolution in sight. In the meantime attempts have been made to reduce the number of whales caught each year. However, critics feel that these have been far too weak. A humpback whale breaching off the coast of Western Australia Regulating whaling Since 1946, the whale industry has been regulated by an inter-governmental body called the International Whaling Commission (IWC). It currently has members from 88 countries. In 1986, following the success of the Greenpeace campaign a decade earlier, the IWC imposed a blanket ban on all commercial whaling. It permitted continued whale harvesting by indigenous (traditional) peoples in countries like Canada, in recognition of their right to be culturally different. Has the ban worked? The ban has only been partly effective. According to critics, the number of whales harvested by a few countries Japan, Norway and Iceland remains too high. In fact, the number killed is now twice as high as it was 15 years ago. This is because at the turn of the millennium the overharvesting of the early 1980s had led to a reduction in the number of mature whales, and the catch went down (see Box 1). Today records show that around 2,000 whales are caught per annum, but the real figure could be higher. Norway and Iceland simply ignore the ban, while Japan uses the excuse of scientific research to stay within the letter but certainly not the spirit of the IWC regulations. Though some whale species are now largely free from commercial exploitation, others are harvested at levels anti-whalers consider far too high (see Tables 1 and 2, p.24). Why does whaling continue? Why has governmental regulation failed to eliminate commercial whaling? In the countries mentioned above the consumption of whales remains culturally important, as it does in those indigenous communities the IWC allows to whale. In countries morally opposed to whaling like the UK whaling is not an important political issue when compared to things like trade or energy security. As a result, countries like the UK have not imposed meaningful penalties on the major whaling nations. Nor have they paid the money necessary to ensure that there is a robust system in February 2014 23

place to monitor the exact number of whales caught each year. In short, the IWC lacked the resources and tools to translate its mid-1980s policy decision into effective action. Trading to protect the environment Around the time of the Greenpeace save the whales campaign a group of economists suggested a way of protecting the nonhuman world from harm without the need for direct governmental regulation. These environmental economists, as they soon became called, argued that one could trade environmental bads for environmental goods. In other words, they reasoned that if enough people valued things like wild tigers they would be willing to pay those who valued such creatures dead not to kill them. The people who wanted to protect the tigers could, in theory, hail from anywhere in the world. Only recently has this approach been suggested as a solution to the continued problem as the IWC and anti-whalers see it of over-whaling. A new approach to saving whales Writing in the world-leading journal Nature, three US academics have recently outlined a scheme to make it too costly for whalers to continue to harvest whales commercially. Christopher Costello, Leah Gerber and Steven Gaines (2012) explain their scheme as follows. First, the IWC would agree an annual cap on global whale catches. Second, each IWC member would be allocated a certain proportion of the catch quota (e.g. 1% or 25%). Third, all members would then have three options. They could choose not to use their allocation, they could choose to defer its use for a year, or they could choose to give it to one or more parties (e.g. whalers or whale conservation organisations). Fourth, these parties could either exercise the right to harvest whales or could sell this right to willing buyers. This scheme would mean that the number of whales harvested per annum would depend on how much of the global quota was used and who in the end the quota was used by. For instance, an anti-whaling organisation like the Sea Shepherd Conservation Society (the SSCS) might purchase a quarter of Iceland s annual quota. This money would go directly to sailors and onshore processors who rely on whaling to make a living. They would be compensated for whaling less than they Table 1 Global whale catch by IWC members, 1982 83 (just before the ban on commercial whaling) Area/country Bowhead Bryde s Fin Grey Humpback Minke Sei Sperm Total Antarctic 6,447 6,447 Brazil 625 625 Spain 120 120 Portugal 21 21 Denmark (Greenland) 8 15 23 Faroes and West Indies 5 1 6 Iceland 144 100 244 Japan 536 393 929 USA 9 2 11 USSR 168 168 Philippines 9 9 Peru 149 149 Chile (scientific purposes) 3 1 4 Total 9 697 278 170 16 7,072 100 414 8,756 Source: Secretariat of the IWC Table 2 Global whale catch by IWC members, 2008 09 (more than 20 years after the ban on commercial whaling) Area/country Bowhead Bryde s Fin Gray Humpback Minke Sei Sperm Total Arctic (Japanese catch) 1 680 681 Denmark (Greenland) 3 10 168 181 Iceland 125 814 206 Norway 484 484 West Indies 1 1 Japan 50 165 101 1 317 Korea 16 16 Former USSR 116 116 USA 38 38 Total 41 50 136 116 1 1,594 101 1 2,040 Source: Secretariat of the IWC Note: Some IWC members ceased whaling after 1985, hence the difference from Table 1. 24 Geography Review

Greenpeace boat intercepting a Japanese whaling ship during protest action, 2002 Whales being processed in a Japanese town, around 1800 would otherwise do. The SSCS would achieve its ethical objectives directly, rather than having the IWC act as an intermediary. If enough organisations and individuals paid enough money to dissuade whalers from whaling, in the long run whaling might become a thing of the past. According to Costello, Gerber and Gaines, the power of antiwhaling consumers could outweigh the market power of those who consume whale meat and blubber. A market in whale lives: the arguments Strengths What are the plus-points of the scheme outlined above? Think about the IWC ban. It has worked for some species (notably minke whales). It has created a moral stand-off: the IWC s majority of anti-whaling countries wish to change the behaviour of countries like Norway. References and further reading Costello, C., Gerber, L. and Gaines, S. (2012) A market approach to saving the whales, Nature 12 January, Vol. 481, pp. 139 40. Four letters of response to this article, some critical of it, appear in the Correspondence section of Nature in the issues published 9 and 16 February 2012, Vol. 482. The IWC website is a good source of information on past and present approaches to regulating global whale catches. It also contains useful updates on current policy discussions among IWC members. http:// iwc.int/home In this light, the scheme proposed by Costello, Gerber and Gaines has four advantages. First, it incentivises whaling nations to reduce their whale catch over time. It uses a carrot rather than stick approach. Second, it is morally neutral. It creates a means whereby pro- and anti-whaling countries, organisations and individuals can realise their objectives through market transactions. By setting-up a cap and trade scheme for whales, the IWC could avoid antagonising whaling nations and act as an honest broker between pro- and anti-whaling interests. Third, there are precedents that suggest the proposed scheme might work to reduce whale harvests, for example successful schemes to reduce sulphur dioxide emissions in the USA and over-fishing in New Zealand. Finally, anti-whaling organisations currently spend about $25 million a year on publicity and activities designed to highlight the cruelty of whaling. If one looks at the current price of whale meat and blubber, that money could be better spent saving hundreds A fin whale being cut up, Hvalfjordur, Iceland. The Icelandic government allowed fin whales to be hunted again in 2006 after numbers in its waters had stabilised of whales in the cap and trade scheme detailed above. The money spent on campaigning is doing little to reduce whale catches, even as it sways the hearts and minds of millions of people who oppose whaling (but who can do little to strengthen the IWC). Weaknesses Despite the above arguments in favour of the idea, the concept of consumers paying to keep whales alive is not problem-free. First, it presumes that those involved in whaling are willing to compromise their cultural beliefs and way of life in order to acquire money. Second, establishing the correct annual cap on whale harvests is technically demanding. Whales are mobile and often highly dispersed. Determining the population size of each whale species is very tricky indeed. As a result, determining what is a sustainable catch per whale species is challenging. Third, like all cap and trade schemes, the proposed whale scheme rests on what are called counter-factual assumptions. It February 2014 25

assumes that whales not caught in any given year would have been caught had not an organisation like Sea Shepherds paid money. But by definition this assumption cannot be proven since only if additional whales had been harvested could it be verified. Fourth, what happens if enough consumers can no long afford to pay to keep whales alive? For instance, when economic recessions and depressions hit, people and organisations have far less disposal income to spend. Would the scheme work? These four problems aside, let us suppose that the IWC chose to implement the proposed scheme from 2016. After all, its blanket ban has failed to eliminate large-scale whaling and it is surely time to try something new. To what degree would a new market in whale life and death reduce global harvests? There is a good chance that the major whaling nations would sell a meaningful portion of their quota to anti-whaling groups. Whaling is difficult it is expensive and demanding of time and energy. Receiving payments to whale less would surely incentivise many whalers in Japan, Iceland and Norway (among others). It would also give them the time to explore other options for making a living. However, if the IWC progressively lowered the annual cap and more rigorously monitored whale catches there is the risk of price inflation. As whale meat and blubber became scarce, prices might rise, making it more costly for anti-whalers to participate in the trading scheme. At the same time, a large black market could emerge in which whalers earned extra income by catching and selling whales illegally. In the long run it is unlikely that commercial whaling could be entirely eliminated. Many individuals and organisations, like the Sea Shepherds, regard this as ethically unacceptable in any case. However, if the scheme proposed by Costello, Gerber and Gaines were to reduce whale catches by even 25% that would surely be success of a kind. Questions for further discussion 1 Can you think of a way that the IWC could reduce the number of whales caught globally without implementing the scheme suggested by Costello, Gerber and Gaines? In other words, is direct governmental regulation of whaling still an option? 2 If a new black market in whale meat and blubber were to emerge as the cap was lowered over time, what would the IWC need to do to eliminate it? 3 In your view, is consumers spending money a good way for people to express their ethical preferences? Should some things be too valuable to have a price placed on them? Noel Castree is professor of geography at Manchester University. Key points Recent shifts in environmental policy worldwide invite consumers to pay for the conservation of environmental goods. Recently, one such policy has been suggested as a way to reduce the ongoing problem of too many whales being caught per annum. The policy places an annual cap on the global whale catch, divides the catch into shares, and allows pro- and anti-whaling organisations and individuals to enter into monetary transactions with each other. Anti-whalers can thus pay whalers not to catch so many whales in future. Though the proposed policy contains a number of flaws, it stands a good chance of reducing the global whale catch by several hundred per annum in the short to medium term. STUDENT UNIT GUIDES NEW EDITION Clear focused support for your best possible grade Written by examiners, these full-colour guides are ideal preparation for your AS and A2 exams: Understand the content of each unit with topic summaries, knowledge check questions and an index Be clear about what is being asked of you in the exam and the skills you need to show to answer questions successfully Practise for better grades with the help of exam-style questions and graded student responses ebooks Student Unit Guides are available as ebooks from some or all of the following websites: Amazon www.amazon.co.uk Apple www.apple.com Dawsonera www.dawsonbooks.co.uk EBL www.eblib.com Ebooks.com www.ebooks.com Ebrary www.ebrary.com/corp etextbooks www.dynamic-learning.co.uk Myilibrary www.myilibrary.com Netlibrary www.netlibrary.com RM Books www.rmbookshelf.com There are AS/A2 guides for AQA, Edexcel, OCR and WJEC 9.99 7.99 each* when you use code WI0002935 at www.hoddereducation.co.uk *offer expires 30 June 2014 Visit www.hoddereducation.co.uk/student-unit-guides today for information on all the titles in the series and simple online ordering, or contact our customer services department on 01235 827827 26 Geography Review