Measuring Returns to Scale in Nineteenth-Century French Industry Technical Appendix

Similar documents
a) List and define all assumptions for multiple OLS regression. These are all listed in section 6.5

Robust specification testing in regression: the FRESET test and autocorrelated disturbances

What Causes the Favorite-Longshot Bias? Further Evidence from Tennis

The Simple Linear Regression Model ECONOMETRICS (ECON 360) BEN VAN KAMMEN, PHD

Efficiency Wages in Major League Baseball Starting. Pitchers Greg Madonia

An Empirical Comparison of Regression Analysis Strategies with Discrete Ordinal Variables

Chapter 12 Practice Test

Hitting with Runners in Scoring Position

Announcements. Lecture 19: Inference for SLR & Transformations. Online quiz 7 - commonly missed questions

Behavior under Social Pressure: Empty Italian Stadiums and Referee Bias

Rossana Merola ILO, Research Department

Learning about Banks Net Worth and the Slow Recovery after the Financial Crisis

Discussion: Illusions of Sparsity by Giorgio Primiceri

Appendix for: Product Differentiation and Mergers in the Carbonated Soft Drink Industry

What does it take to produce an Olympic champion? A nation naturally

Modelling residential prices with cointegration techniques and automatic selection algorithms

ECO 745: Theory of International Economics. Jack Rossbach Fall Lecture 6

College/high school median annual earnings gap,

Legendre et al Appendices and Supplements, p. 1

Are Workers Rewarded for Inconsistent Performance?

Name May 3, 2007 Math Probability and Statistics

A REVIEW AND EVALUATION OF NATURAL MORTALITY FOR THE ASSESSMENT AND MANAGEMENT OF YELLOWFIN TUNA IN THE EASTERN PACIFIC OCEAN

Random Coefficient Models for Time-Series Cross-Section Data: Monte Carlo Experiments

Analysis of 2015 Trail Usage Patterns along the Great Allegheny Passage

Accounting for the Evolution of U.S. Wage Inequality

Journal of Quantitative Analysis in Sports

OR DUNGENESS CRAB FISHERY:

Random Coefficient Models for Time-Series Cross-Section Data: Monte Carlo Experiments of Finite Sample Properties

Nonlife Actuarial Models. Chapter 7 Bühlmann Credibility

Going with your Gut: The (In)accuracy of Forecast Revisions in a Football Score Prediction Game

1 Introduction. 2 EAD and Derived Factors

Multiple Blockholders, Price Informativeness, and Firm Value

Journal of Sports Economics 2000; 1; 299

Novel empirical correlations for estimation of bubble point pressure, saturated viscosity and gas solubility of crude oils

A Comparison of Trend Scoring and IRT Linking in Mixed-Format Test Equating

PROPAGATION OF LONG-PERIOD WAVES INTO AN ESTUARY THROUGH A NARROW INLET

QED. Queen s Economics Department Working Paper No Correcting for bias in hot hand analysis: Analyzing performance streaks in youth golf

Deriving an Optimal Fantasy Football Draft Strategy

Section I: Multiple Choice Select the best answer for each problem.

What Can We Learn From the Current Crisis in Argentina?

Evaluation of Regression Approaches for Predicting Yellow Perch (Perca flavescens) Recreational Harvest in Ohio Waters of Lake Erie

A N E X P L O R AT I O N W I T H N E W Y O R K C I T Y TA X I D ATA S E T

GLMM standardisation of the commercial abalone CPUE for Zones A-D over the period

Applying Generalized Pareto Curves to Inequality Analysis

On the Allocation of Time A Quantitative Analysis of the US and France

Standard Errors in the U.S. Regional Price Parities (RPPs)

Angler Use, Harvest and Economic Assessment on Trout Stocked Streams in Pennsylvania

Honest Mirror: Quantitative Assessment of Player Performances in an ODI Cricket Match

the 54th Annual Conference of the Association of Collegiate School of Planning (ACSP) in Philadelphia, Pennsylvania November 2 nd, 2014

Business Cycles. Chris Edmond NYU Stern. Spring 2007

The Velocity of Money Revisited

CHAPTER 10 TOTAL RECREATIONAL FISHING DAMAGES AND CONCLUSIONS

Structural Change with Endogenous Input-Output Linkages

Longevity Risk in China and its Financial Impact: Evidence from Model Test

GENETICS OF RACING PERFORMANCE IN THE AMERICAN QUARTER HORSE: II. ADJUSTMENT FACTORS AND CONTEMPORARY GROUPS 1'2

Systematic Review and Meta-analysis of Bicycle Helmet Efficacy to Mitigate Head, Face and Neck Injuries

The Effects of Altitude on Soccer Match Outcomes

Effects of sea lion predation on Willamette River winter steelhead viability

Reference- Dependence in Dutch Football

Exorbitant Privilege and Exorbitant Duty

Human Capital Composition and Economic Growth at a Regional Level.

arxiv: v1 [math.co] 11 Apr 2018

Forecasting Persistent Data with Possible Structural Breaks: Old School and New School. Lessons Using OECD Unemployment Rates

July 9, SINTEF Fisheries and Aquaculture 1

3. Real-time operation and review of complex circuits, allowing the weighing of alternative design actions.

Prediction Market and Parimutuel Mechanism

Common Factors in Commodity Futures Curves

Analysis of Variance. Copyright 2014 Pearson Education, Inc.

Safety Analyses At Signalized Intersections Considering Spatial, Temporal And Site Correlation

An Application of Signal Detection Theory for Understanding Driver Behavior at Highway-Rail Grade Crossings

Swinburne Research Bank

Introduction. Forestry, Wildlife and Fisheries Graduate Seminar Demand for Wildlife Hunting in the Southeastern United States

China from a Macroeconomist s Perspective. Kim J. Ruhl

y ) s x x )(y i (x i r = 1 n 1 s y Statistics Lecture 7 Exploring Data , y 2 ,y n (x 1 ),,(x n ),(x 2 ,y 1 How two variables vary together

Competitive Performance of Elite Olympic-Distance Triathletes: Reliability and Smallest Worthwhile Enhancement

MODELLING THE EFFECT OF HEALTH RISK PERCEPTION ON

At each type of conflict location, the risk is affected by certain parameters:

Instrumental Variables

Macroeconomics Measurements

A Hedonic Price Analysis of Risk Preferences in Yearling Thoroughbred Buyers. Xiurui Iris Cui

Determination of the Design Load for Structural Safety Assessment against Gas Explosion in Offshore Topside

Richard S. Marken The RAND Corporation

Kinetic Energy Analysis for Soccer Players and Soccer Matches

QSPS Conference. May, 2013 Utah State University

Labor Markets. Chris Edmond NYU Stern. Spring 2007

Delta-lognormal and multinomial approaches to index development for parrotfish, silk snapper, and queen snapper from Puerto Rican Trip Tickets

Trade Integration and Political Radicalization: German Evidence from the Rise of Eastern Manufacturing Competition

COMPLETING THE RESULTS OF THE 2013 BOSTON MARATHON

Smart-Walk: An Intelligent Physiological Monitoring System for Smart Families

Essays on Sports Economics

Relevance of Questions from past Level III Essay Exams

Navigate to the golf data folder and make it your working directory. Load the data by typing

The final set in a tennis match: four years at Wimbledon 1

Figure 1a. Top 1% income share: China vs USA vs France

Journal of Human Sport and Exercise E-ISSN: Universidad de Alicante España

CALIBRATION OF THE PLATOON DISPERSION MODEL BY CONSIDERING THE IMPACT OF THE PERCENTAGE OF BUSES AT SIGNALIZED INTERSECTIONS

The Transition of Reproductive Life Course in Japan; the Lexis-Layer Decomposition Analysis of Fertility Decline 1

One-factor ANOVA by example

Building an NFL performance metric

Product Technical Bulletin #48

Transcription:

Measuring Returns to Scale in Nineteenth-Century French Industry Technical Appendix Ulrich Doraszelski Hoover Institution, Stanford University March 2004 Formal Derivations Gross-output vs value-added production function. With the Cobb-Douglas form used by Sicsic (994), increasing returns to scale in the value-added production function are equivalent to increasing returns to scale in the gross-output production function. The choice between value-added and gross-output production function is nevertheless not innocuous because returns to scale estimated from the value-added production function overstate (understate) the degree of returns to scale in the case of increasing (decreasing) returns. To see this, let i =,..., N index observations and let y i denote output, l i labor, m i materials, and k i capital. Consider the gross-output production function y i = e β 0 l β l i mβm i k β k i e ɛ i and define the value-added production function to be the solution to max m i py i w m m i, Stanford, CA 94305-600, U.S.A., doraszelski@hoover.stanford.edu.

where p is the price of output and w m is the price of intermediate goods. Then the value-added production function is given by v i = e β 0 βm ( pβm w m = e γ 0 l γ l i kγ k i e η i. ) βm βm l β l βm i k β k βm i e βm ɛ i Returns to scale are computed from the value-added production function as γ l + γ k and as β l + β m + β k from the gross-output production function. But γ l + γ k β l + β m + β k β l + β m + β k, which shows that returns to scale estimated from the value-added production function overstate (understate) the degree of returns to scale in the case of increasing (decreasing) returns. Sicsic s (994) heteroskedasitcity correction. Sicsic (994) uses the average establishment as the unit of observation and tries to correct for the resulting heteroskedasticity by dividing by the square root of the number of establishments. Since his model is log-linear, however, it is not consistent with using the number of establishments as weight. Indeed, when taken literally, Sicsic s (994) heteroskedasticity correction induces a correlation between error term and regressors. To see this, let i =,..., N index observations and j =,..., n i index establishments within the ith observation. Let v ij denote the value added of the jth establishment in the ith observation, and let l ij and k ij be defined analogously for labor and capital inputs, respectively. If the individual firm s value-added production function is of the Cobb- Douglas form, v ij = e γ 0 l γ l ij kγ k ij eη ij, then taking logs and averaging over establishments yields ( ln v i = γ 0 + γ l ln l i + γ k ln k i + η i n i n i ln v ij ln v i ) } {{ } composite error term 2

+γ l ( n i n i ) ( ln l ij ln l i + γ k n i n i ln k ij ln k i ) } {{ } composite error term (cont d) where v i = n i ni v ij etc. Instead of being proportional to n i, the variance of the composite error term is a complicated function of n i that also depends on the regressors. Moreover, the regressors are correlated with the composite error term which causes the coefficient estimates to be biased. Aggregate vs average establishment. Returns to scale estimated from average establishments in general overstate (understate) the degree of returns to scale in the case of increasing (decreasing) returns to scale. To see this, let j =,..., n index establishments within a collective observation. For the sake of the argument let y j denote the gross-output and x j the generic input of the jth establishment and assume that its production function is given by y j = x α j. Note that y = n n y j = n n x α j ( n ) α n x j = x α α, which implies ln y α ln x α. The degree of returns to scale is estimated to ln y be ˆα = ln x. Hence, ˆα α α provided that x >. On the other hand, if the aggregate establishment is used as the unit of observation, then the degree of returns to scale is estimated to be ˆα = ln n y j ln n x j, which tends to understate (overstate) the degree of returns to scale in the case of increasing (decreasing) returns to scale., Monte Carlo Experiment I consider the production function y i = e β 0 l β l i mβm i k β k i e ɛ i. Following the recent literature on production function estimation, I assume that the firm knows the productivity shock when it chooses its inputs (Olley & Pakes 996, Levinsohn & Petrin 2003). As I argue in the main text, this implies that l i, m i, 3

and k i are positively correlated with ɛ i. One suspects that this causes overestimation of β l, β m, and β k, and thus of the degree of returns to scale. However, this is not generally true, since the biases of the OLS estimators for β l, β m, and β k also depend on the covariances of the regressors. To investigate wether endogeneity indeed leads to overestimation of the degree of returns to scale I therefore conduct a Monte Carlo experiment. Since the biases of the OLS estimators for β l, β m, and β k depend on the covariance between the regressors, (ln l i, ln m i, ln k i ), the Monte Carlo samples are generated such that the covariance of the simulated inputs equals the covariance of the observed inputs in my data sets, and similarly for the means of the regressors. Also the variance of the productivity shock and the parameters of the production function are estimated from the data sets using OLS. Finally, the Monte Carlo sample sizes are equal to the actual sample sizes in my data sets. It remains to choose the correlations between error term and regressors. Assuming that each regressor can have a correlation of 0,, or with the error term yields 27 2 correlation patterns. However, the covariance between the regressors restricts the set of possible correlations between error term and regressors. Hence, if a correlation pattern is not feasible, I choose the closest one (in terms of Euclidian distance) that is. For a given correlation pattern and industry, the simulation experiment proceeds as follows. Imposing the correlations between the error term and the regressors, I generate S = 500 samples of size N from a multivariate normal distribution. Then I estimate the production function for each Monte Carlo sample and calculate the bias of estimates of the degree of returns to scale. The results are presented in Tables -4. Tables and 2 contain results for the French industrial census of 839-47 using either the aggregate (Table ) or the average (Table 2) establishment as the unit of observation. Tables 3 and 4 correspond to Tables and 2 and report results for the French industrial census of 86-65. summary, for both French industrial censuses, one can be reasonably confident that even a small amount of positive correlation between the productivity shock and the inputs leads to overestimation of the degree of returns to scale. Also the bias appears to be quite substantial even for moderate correlations. In 4

correlation between ɛ and codbrag ln(l) ln(m) ln(k) 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 0 2 3 4 5 6 0 0 0 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0 0 0.5 0.06 0.4 0.05 0.08 0.08 0.07 0.0 0.2 0. 0.07 0.02 0. 0.04 0.0 0. 0.7 0 0 0.2 0.23 0.09 0.3 0.4 0.3 0.5 0.9 0.2 0.3 0.04 0.9 0.07 0.05 0.9 0.30 0 0.5 0 0.0-0.02 0.05-0.0-0.03 0.0-0. -0.02-0.04 0.06 0.08-0.0 0.02-0.0-0. 0.00 0 0.5 0.5 0.08 0.2 0.0 0.07 0.05 0.08-0.0 0.09 0.08 0.3 0.0 0.0 0.06 0.0 0.0 0.6 0 0.5 0.4 0.24 0.5 0.4 0.4 0.5 0.2 0.9 0.2 0.8 0.0 0.20 0.09 0.06 0.5 0.3 0 0 0.05 0.02 0.0 0.02 0.00 0.04-0.06 0.00 0.00 0.0 0.2 0.02 0.04 0.02-0.06 0.0 0 0.5 0.0 0.2 0.5 0.08 0.07 0.0 0.0 0.09 0.0 0.7 0.4 0. 0.08 0.05 0.03 0.6 0 0.5 0.24 0.8 0.5 0.4 0.6 0. 0.9 0.22 0.22 0.5 0.20 0. 0.09 0.4 0.28 0.5 0 0 0.08 0.3 0.06 0.08 0.0 0.0 0.9 0. 0.9 0.06 0.0 0.07 0.05 0.2 0.8 0.09 0.5 0 0.5 0.5 0.27 0. 0.6 0.8 0.7 0.28 0.23 0.30 0.3 0.03 0.8 0.09 0.3 0.28 0.26 0.5 0 0.8 0.33 0.5 0.9 0.2 0.2 0.27 0.29 0.37 0.20 0.06 0.24 0. 0.3 0.29 0.38 0.5 0.5 0 0.09 0. 0. 0.07 0.07 0. 0.08 0.08 0.5 0.2 0.09 0.06 0.07 0. 0.06 0.09 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.6 0.25 0.6 0.5 0.5 0.8 0.7 0.20 0.26 0.9 0. 0.7 0. 0.2 0.7 0.26 0.5 0.5 0.22 0.38 0.2 0.22 0.23 0.25 0.26 0.3 0.37 0.26 0.3 0.27 0.4 0.4 0.28 0.42 0.5 0 0. 0.2 0.5 0.08 0.06 0.3 0.05 0.09 0.3 0.7 0.4 0.06 0.09 0.0 0.03 0.0 0.5 0.5 0.7 0.23 0.2 0.4 0.3 0.9 0.0 0.8 0.23 0.24 0.8 0.6 0.2 0.2 0.0 0.25 0.5 0.22 0.35 0.25 0.2 0.2 0.24 0.20 0.29 0.35 0.28 0.9 0.25 0.6 0.5 0.22 0.37 0 0 0.4 0.22 0. 0.2 0.4 0.8 0.23 0.9 0.28 0.2 0.04 0.0 0.09 0.5 0.20 0.7 0 0.5 0.9 0.33 0.6 0.8 0.2 0.23 0.3 0.29 0.40 0.9 0.06 0.9 0.2 0.8 0.30 0.32 0 0.22 0.38 0.9 0.22 0.25 0.25 0.33 0.33 0.45 0.24 0.09 0.25 0.4 0.9 0.34 0.39 0.5 0 0.6 0.23 0.6 0.4 0.5 0.20 0.2 0.9 0.29 0.7 0.0 0. 0. 0.7 0.8 0.8 0.5 0.5 0.23 0.37 0.22 0.22 0.23 0.28 0.33 0.3 0.43 0.25 0.2 0.22 0.5 0.22 0.3 0.34 0.5 0.25 0.43 0.24 0.25 0.28 0.29 0.35 0.37 0.50 0.30 0.5 0.28 0.8 0.22 0.36 0.43 0 0.7 0.23 0.9 0.4 0.4 0.20 0.7 0.9 0.27 0.2 0.5 0.2 0.2 0.7 0.4 0.9 0.5 0.23 0.34 0.25 0.2 0.2 0.27 0.25 0.28 0.39 0.29 0.9 0.22 0.6 0.2 0.24 0.3 0.26 0.4 0.27 0.25 0.26 0.29 0.3 0.35 0.46 0.32 0.20 0.28 0.8 0.22 0.3 0.40 Table : Bias in estimates of the degree of returns to scale for the various industries in the French industrial census 839-47. Unit of observation is the aggregate establishment. 5

correlation between ɛ and codbrag ln(l) ln(m) ln(k) 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 0 2 3 4 5 6 0 0 0 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0 0 0.5 0.07 0.3 0.05 0.09 0.09 0.0 0.0 0.3 0.8 0.07 0.09 0.6 0.05 0.03 0.3 0.24 0 0 0.2 0.2 0.09 0.4 0.6 0.7 0.4 0.9 0.35 0.3 0.4 0.26 0.0 0.06 0.22 0.43 0 0.5 0-0.0-0.03 0.05-0.04-0.04-0.03-0.3-0.04-0.06 0.04-0.05-0.0 0.02 0.00-0.4-0.06 0 0.5 0.5 0.06 0.0 0.0 0.05 0.05 0.07-0.04 0.09 0.3 0.0 0.04 0.05 0.07 0.03 0.00 0.7 0 0.5 0.3 0.22 0.5 0.3 0.5 0.7 0.0 0.9 0.3 0.6 0.4 0.22 0.2 0.08 0.7 0.4 0 0 0.02 0.00 0.0-0.0-0.0-0.0-0.07-0.0-0.05 0.07-0.0-0.06 0.05 0.03-0.09-0.08 0 0.5 0.08 0.0 0.5 0.05 0.07 0.07-0.0 0.08 0.3 0.4 0.06 0.06 0.0 0.07 0.02 0.2 0 0.4 0.2 0.9 0.3 0.6 0.5 0.09 0.8 0.3 0.9 0.4 0.9 0.4 0. 0.5 0.32 0.5 0 0 0.08 0.4 0.06 0.09 0.2 0.3 0.20 0. 0.29 0.07 0.2 0.2 0.07 0. 0.20 0.8 0.5 0 0.5 0.5 0.27 0. 0.7 0.2 0.23 0.27 0.23 0.47 0.4 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.3 0.32 0.42 0.5 0 0.8 0.32 0.5 0.20 0.25 0.26 0.25 0.29 0.60 0.9 0.23 0.3 0.6 0.4 0.33 0.53 0.5 0.5 0 0.08 0. 0. 0.04 0.08 0.0 0.06 0.07 0.23 0. 0.08 0.0 0.09 0.0 0.06 0. 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.24 0.6 0.3 0.7 0.20 0.6 0.20 0.42 0.7 0.6 0.7 0.5 0.3 0.9 0.36 0.5 0.5 0.2 0.36 0.2 0.22 0.26 0.29 0.24 0.3 0.59 0.24 0.25 0.32 0.20 0.6 0.32 0.54 0.5 0 0.08 0. 0.5 0.04 0.06 0.09 0.03 0.08 0.9 0.4 0.07-0.02 0. 0. 0.0 0.08 0.5 0.5 0.4 0.2 0.2 0.0 0.4 0.7 0.07 0.6 0.36 0.2 0.3 0.0 0.7 0.4 0.0 0.29 0.5 0.20 0.33 0.25 0.8 0.23 0.25 0.7 0.28 0.52 0.25 0.22 0.24 0.2 0.7 0.24 0.44 0 0 0.3 0.24 0. 0.2 0.7 0.22 0.22 0.9 0.49 0.2 0.7 0.2 0.4 0.5 0.22 0.34 0 0.5 0.9 0.33 0.6 0.9 0.25 0.28 0.29 0.29 0.65 0.9 0.24 0.24 0.9 0.8 0.33 0.49 0 0.2 0.38 0.9 0.22 0.29 0.30 0.3 0.34 0.70 0.23 0.27 0.3 0.2 0.9 0.38 0.55 0.5 0 0.5 0.23 0.6 0.2 0.7 0.22 0.9 0.8 0.50 0.6 0.7 0.0 0.5 0.7 0.9 0.29 0.5 0.5 0.22 0.37 0.22 0.2 0.27 0.3 0.30 0.30 0.70 0.24 0.27 0.24 0.22 0.22 0.34 0.49 0.5 0.25 0.42 0.25 0.24 0.3 0.33 0.33 0.37 0.73 0.29 0.30 0.32 0.24 0.23 0.39 0.55 0 0.5 0.23 0.20 0. 0.6 0.20 0.5 0.8 0.43 0.9 0.6 0.07 0.6 0.7 0.4 0.23 0.5 0.2 0.33 0.25 0.8 0.24 0.27 0.22 0.27 0.59 0.26 0.23 0.8 0.2 0.22 0.25 0.40 0.24 0.40 0.27 0.23 0.29 0.3 0.28 0.34 0.66 0.30 0.29 0.28 0.24 0.23 0.34 0.49 Table 2: Bias in estimates of the degree of returns to scale for the various industries in the French industrial census 839-47. Unit of observation is the average establishment. 6

correlation between ɛ and codbrag ln(l) ln(m) ln(k) 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 0 2 3 4 5 6 0 0 0 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00-0.0 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0 0 0.5 0.06 0.05 0.04 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.0-0.0-0.0 0.20 0.08 0.06 0.0 0.07 0.06 0 0 0.08 0. 0.06 0.09 0.07 0.09 0.08 0.05 0.03 0.0 0.24 0.2 0.07 0.05 0. 0.09 0 0.5 0-0.0 0.09 0.0 0.04 0.00 0.00-0.02 0.0 0.09 0.03 0.05-0.02-0.04 0.07-0.02 0.02 0 0.5 0.5 0.05 0.5 0.05 0.08 0.05 0.05 0.03 0.02 0.08 0.02 0.23 0.06 0.0 0.08 0.05 0.07 0 0.5 0.09 0.9 0.08 0.2 0.09 0. 0.09 0.06 0.0 0.05 0.28 0.3 0.06 0.0 0.2 0.2 0 0 0.02 0.7 0.03 0.07 0.02 0.03 0.02 0.04 0.3 0.07 0.08 0.02-0.02 0. 0.02 0.05 0 0.5 0.06 0.22 0.06 0.2 0.06 0.07 0.06 0.06 0.5 0.08 0.20 0.08 0.0 0.3 0.07 0.09 0 0.0 0.26 0.09 0.5 0.0 0.2 0.0 0.09 0.6 0.09 0.28 0.4 0.06 0.5 0.3 0.3 0.5 0 0 0.04 0.06 0.03 0.04 0.04 0.07 0.07 0.09 0.06 0.0-0.08 0.07 0.06 0.04 0.09 0.04 0.5 0 0.5 0.09 0. 0.07 0.09 0.08 0.2 0.2 0.0 0.06 0.09 0. 0.5 0. 0.05 0.6 0.0 0.5 0 0.2 0.6 0.09 0.3 0. 0.5 0.3 0.2 0.08 0.08 0.24 0.8 0.2 0.09 0.8 0.3 0.5 0.5 0 0.03 0.5 0.04 0.08 0.04 0.07 0.06 0.0 0.5 0.3-0.03 0.06 0.0 0. 0.08 0.06 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.09 0.2 0.08 0.3 0.09 0.2 0. 0.2 0.4 0.2 0.6 0.4 0.07 0.2 0.4 0. 0.5 0.5 0.4 0.26 0. 0.7 0.3 0.7 0.5 0.3 0.5 0. 0.32 0.2 0.2 0.4 0.20 0.7 0.5 0 0.05 0.23 0.06 0. 0.05 0.08 0.07 0.0 0.9 0.5 0.07 0.08 0.02 0.5 0.08 0.09 0.5 0.5 0.08 0.3 0.09 0.6 0.09 0.3 0.0 0.3 0.22 0.5 0.20 0.3 0.04 0.8 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.3 0.33 0.2 0.20 0.3 0.7 0.5 0.5 0.22 0.5 0.3 0.20 0.09 0.9 0.20 0.8 0 0 0.06 0. 0.05 0.08 0.06 0. 0.0 0.3 0.0 0.4-0.0 0. 0.08 0.08 0.4 0.08 0 0.5 0. 0.7 0.09 0.2 0.0 0.6 0.5 0.6 0.2 0.5 0.0 0.7 0.2 0.0 0.20 0.2 0 0.4 0.22 0. 0.6 0.3 0.9 0.7 0.7 0.4 0.4 0.2 0.2 0.4 0.3 0.23 0.6 0.5 0 0.07 0.20 0.07 0.2 0.07 0.2 0. 0.5 0.7 0.8 0.02 0.2 0.07 0.3 0.5 0.0 0.5 0.5 0.2 0.26 0. 0.7 0.2 0.8 0.7 0.20 0.20 0.20 0. 0.20 0.2 0.6 0.22 0.6 0.5 0.6 0.3 0.4 0.2 0.5 0.22 0.20 0.2 0.20 0.9 0.27 0.25 0.5 0.8 0.27 0.20 0 0.08 0.26 0.09 0.5 0.09 0.3 0.2 0.6 0.22 0.9 0.09 0.3 0.06 0.7 0.5 0.2 0.5 0.2 0.33 0.2 0.20 0.2 0.8 0.6 0.20 0.26 0.22 0.8 0.9 0.09 0.2 0.2 0.7 0.7 0.36 0.5 0.24 0.6 0.22 0.20 0.22 0.27 0.2 0.30 0.25 0.3 0.23 0.27 0.2 Table 3: Bias in estimates of the degree of returns to scale for the various industries in the French industrial census 86-65. Unit of observation is the aggregate establishment. 7

correlation between ɛ and codbrag ln(l) ln(m) ln(k) 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 0 2 3 4 5 6 0 0 0 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00-0.0 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.0 0 0 0.5 0.03 0.3 0.04 0.05 0.06 0.06 0.04-0.0-0.0-0.03 0.2 0.07 0.04-0.02 0.07 0.06 0 0 0.07 0.20 0.07 0.09 0.09 0.0 0.07 0.03 0.03-0.0 0.26 0.2 0.08 0.02 0.3 0. 0 0.5 0 0.0 0. 0.0 0.03 0.0 0.03-0.03 0.04 0.04 0.05 0.04 0.00 0.0 0.06-0.05 0.04 0 0.5 0.5 0.04 0.24 0.05 0.08 0.07 0.08 0.02 0.03 0.03 0.02 0.23 0.07 0.05 0.05 0.02 0.09 0 0.5 0.09 0.30 0.09 0.2 0.2 0.4 0.07 0.06 0.08 0.03 0.30 0.4 0.09 0.06 0. 0.5 0 0 0.04 0.2 0.04 0.07 0.04 0.06 0.0 0.06 0.09 0.09 0.07 0.04 0.04 0.0-0.02 0.08 0 0.5 0.07 0.30 0.07 0. 0.09 0. 0.04 0.08 0. 0.08 0.2 0.0 0.07 0. 0.04 0.4 0 0. 0.36 0.0 0.5 0.3 0.6 0.08 0.0 0.5 0.08 0.30 0.6 0. 0.2 0.2 0.8 0.5 0 0 0.09 0.03 0.05 0.06 0.04 0.09 0.08 0. 0.20 0.08-0.06 0.09 0.05 0.07 0.4 0.08 0.5 0 0.5 0.2 0.5 0.09 0.0 0.09 0.5 0. 0.0 0.9 0.05 0.4 0.6 0.0 0.06 0.22 0.3 0.5 0 0.3 0.27 0. 0.4 0.3 0.8 0.2 0. 0.8 0.04 0.27 0.9 0.2 0.07 0.23 0.8 0.5 0.5 0 0.09 0.4 0.06 0.09 0.05 0.2 0.05 0.3 0.24 0.3-0.02 0.09 0.07 0.4 0.09 0.2 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.3 0.27 0.0 0.4 0. 0.7 0.09 0.3 0.23 0.0 0.8 0.6 0. 0.2 0.6 0.7 0.5 0.5 0.6 0.38 0.3 0.8 0.6 0.23 0.2 0.3 0.22 0.08 0.35 0.23 0.5 0. 0.23 0.23 0.5 0 0.0 0.25 0.07 0.2 0.07 0.4 0.06 0.4 0.25 0.5 0.07 0. 0.08 0.6 0.08 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.4 0.39 0. 0.7 0.2 0.20 0.08 0.6 0.27 0.4 0.22 0.7 0.2 0.7 0.2 0.22 0.5 0.7 0.43 0.4 0.2 0.7 0.24 0.2 0.7 0.28 0.3 0.34 0.23 0.6 0.7 0.20 0.25 0 0 0.3 0.0 0.08 0.0 0.06 0.6 0.0 0.5 0.30 0.0 0.0 0.4 0.09 0. 0.20 0.4 0 0.5 0.6 0.20 0. 0.4 0. 0.22 0.4 0.7 0.32 0.0 0.3 0.20 0.3 0.2 0.27 0.20 0 0.8 0.30 0.4 0.8 0.5 0.24 0.6 0.8 0.3 0.09 0.25 0.23 0.6 0.2 0.29 0.23 0.5 0 0.5 0.20 0.0 0.3 0.08 0.9 0.0 0.8 0.35 0.5 0.04 0.6 0. 0.6 0.9 0.8 0.5 0.5 0.20 0.3 0.4 0.9 0.4 0.26 0.5 0.22 0.4 0.6 0.5 0.24 0.6 0.8 0.28 0.25 0.5 0.22 0.42 0.7 0.22 0.8 0.29 0.8 0.22 0.38 0.4 0.3 0.28 0.9 0.7 0.33 0.28 0 0.6 0.29 0. 0.6 0. 0.20 0. 0.9 0.36 0.7 0.0 0.7 0.2 0.9 0.8 0.20 0.5 0.20 0.39 0.5 0.2 0.5 0.26 0.4 0.23 0.4 0.9 0.2 0.24 0.6 0.22 0.24 0.26 0.23 0.45 0.8 0.25 0.20 0.29 0.8 0.24 0.4 0.7 0.33 0.29 0.20 0.23 0.30 0.29 Table 4: Bias in estimates of the degree of returns to scale for the various industries in the French industrial census 86-65. Unit of observation is the average establishment. 8

References Levinsohn, J. & Petrin, A. (2003). Estimating production functions using inputs to control for unobservables, Review of Economic Studies 70(2): 37 34. Olley, S. & Pakes, A. (996). The dynamics of productivity in the telecommunications industry, Econometrica 64(6): 263 297. Sicsic, P. (994). Establishment size and economies of scale in 9th-century France, Explorations in Economic History 3: 453 478. 9