Rational Mispricing and Irrational Mispricing in Betting. Markets: Implications for Market Effi ciency Tests

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Rational Mispricing and Irrational Mispricing in Betting. Markets: Implications for Market Effi ciency Tests"

Transcription

1 Rational Mispricing and Irrational Mispricing in Betting Markets: Implications for Market Effi ciency Tests Shingo Goto Toru Yamada May 2017 The views expressed here are our own and do not necessarily reflect the views of Nomura Asset Management. Any errors and inadequacies are our own. The University of Rhode Island, College of Business Administration, Ballentine Hall, 7 Lippitt Road, Kingston, RI 02881, USA. Phone: ; Fax: ; shingo_goto@uri.edu. Nomura Asset Management Co., Ltd. Dai-Ichi Edobashi Building, , Nihonbashi, Chuo-ku, Tokyo , Japan. Phone: ; Fax: ; t-yamada@nomura-am.co.jp.

2 Rational Mispricing and Irrational Mispricing in Betting Markets: Implications for Market Effi ciency Tests A Testing market effi ciency in betting markets does not necessarily get around the joint hypothesis problem because the result depends on the assumed role of bookmakers. In a simple model of monopolistic competition, bookmakers rational pricing induces the Favorite-Longshot Bias even without bettors irrationality (Rational Mispricing) and accommodates bettors irrational beliefs to exploit betting demands (Irrational Mispricing). In European football betting markets, we find significant evidence for both Rational Mispricing and Irrational Mispricing. The former mispricing, though much larger than the latter, depends on bookmakers market power and may have little to do with financial market ineffi ciency. The latter mispricing, albeit smaller, suggests that bettors overstate the persistence of team performance (Hot-Hand Bias), which may explain the reversal in betting returns and asset returns. Increased competition among bookmakers has not weakened the biases, which is diffi cult to explain only by bettors irrationality but consistent with the predicted pricing behavior of bookmakers. Keywords: Market Effi ciency, Fixed-Odds Betting, Favorite-Longshot Bias, Hot-Hand Bias, European Football (Soccer) JEL Classification: G14, G19, G29, L83 1

3 1 Introduction As the joint hypothesis problem (Fama, 1970) makes it diffi cult to address questions of market effi ciency in financial markets, numerous studies have turned to sports betting markets as a ground for testing market effi ciency. 1 Sports betting markets have an attractive feature of fixed goal-posts. That is, each bet has a well-defined termination point at which time its fundamental value is determined exogenously by the game outcomes and known with certainty, whereas the fundamental values are not directly observed in equity markets (e.g. Thaler and Ziemba, 1988). More importantly, since risks associated with game outcomes are mostly idiosyncratic and diversifiable, most predictable patterns in betting returns, if any, would be attributed to mispricing rather than to risk premiums. Consequently, systematic biases in betting prices (odds), 2 when observed, have been primarily attributed to the irrationality of the betting public (bettors in aggregate). Testing market effi ciency in sports betting markets, however, has its own challenges. In particular, the price formation process is often markedly different between sports betting markets and financial markets. Unlike market makers in financial markets, bookmakers in sports betting markets are often exposed to a substantial risk of losing money. 3 According to Levitt (2004), bookmakers can offer bets only because they are more skilled in assessing the 1 Earlier prominent studies of sports betting markets (excluding horse-race gambles) include Zuber, Gandar, and Bowers (1985), Gander, Zuber, O Brien, and Russo (1988), Sauer, Brajer, Ferris, and Marr (1988), Golec and Tamarkin (1991), Brown and Sauer (1993), Woodland and Woodland (1994), Dare and Mac- Donald (1996), Gray and Gray (1997), Gandar, Dare, Brown, and Zuber (1998), and Avery and Chevalier (1999), among others. Moskowitz (2015) has attracted renewed interests in sports betting markets. 2 A betting price is the reciprocal of the odds of the corresponding bet. We use the price and odds interchangeably when the contexts are clear. 3 Leicester City s winning of the English Premier League in was a big surprise to many. Major bookmakers like Ladbrokes Coral and William Hill offered fixed odds of 5,000-1 for the Leicester s victory at the beginning of the season, to rake in a little cash on something that would never happen. This turned into one of the largest mistakes in sports betting history. UK bookmakers lost around $15 million for the bet on the Premier League Winner. Please see Leicester s Betting Line Was a 5,000-to-1 Blunder by J. Robinson on Wall Street Journal, May 5,

4 probabilities of game outcomes than others. Through a detailed analysis of US NFL betting markets, Levitt (2004) shows that bookmakers do not necessarily balance the books, that is, they take some exposure in order to maximize their expected profits. 4 This evidence poses a significant challenge to the testing of market effi ciency in sports betting markets, because questions of market effi ciency can be addressed only when the books are balanced (Woodland and Woodland, 1994, footnote 7). In light of Levitt s (2004) insights, we take a few steps back and ask how bookmakers price-setting behavior can affect our evidence of market (in)effi ciency in sports betting markets. Suppose we find significant evidence for systematic biases in sports betting markets. Without considering the role of bookmakers, can we use the evidence to gain insights into financial market anomalies, such as momentum and reversal (value) effects in asset returns? 5 To address this question, we focus on European football (soccer) betting markets that are primarily characterized by the Fixed-Odds Betting system. In this system, betting odds reflect the amount of dollars that bookmakers commit to pay out to bettors on successful bets per unit dollar. Thus, we can view Fixed-Odds Betting markets as state-contingent claims markets which determine the value of each game outcome. However, the values of game outcomes are not necessarily determined in a competitive equilibrium. In fact, bookmakers in the Fixed Odds Betting system (e.g. European football betting markets) are likely to choose wrong prices deliberately to maximize expected profits as they are exposed to a large risk of unbalanced books. 6 As such, biased prices in Fixed-Odds Betting 4 When bookmakers balance the books, that is, when they equalize the dollar amount of payouts across different outcomes, they receive the vig (commissions, margins) with no risk exposure. 5 Momentum and value effects are widely recognized as pervasive features of financial asset prices (e.g. Asness, Moskowitz, and Pedersen, 2013), though what drive these effects remains an enduring question. Moskowitz (2015) uses value effects and return reversal effects interchangeably. 6 The concern of non-market-clearing prices is more pronounced in the Fixed Odds Betting system (e.g. European football betting markets) than in the Point-Spread Betting system (e.g. US NFL and NBA betting markets), because the books are much more diffi cult to balance in the former than in the latter. 3

5 markets may simply reflect the rational price-setting behavior of bookmakers rather than the irrational wagering behavior of the betting public. This point, however, has been largely overlooked in the voluminous literature on the effi ciency of European football betting markets. 7 To understand the price-setting decision of bookmakers, we consider a simple model of monopolistic competition among them. Using Shin s (1991,1992,1993) model as a guidance, and appealing to the one-shot nature of a Fixed-Odds Betting, we focus on a minimal setup in which a risk-neutral bookmaker solves a single-period expected profit maximization problem. Motivated by Levitt s (2004) insights, each bookmaker is assumed rational in a sense that she knows the objective probabilities of game outcomes. The bookmaker uses the knowledge to exert a market power in her specialties, but she also faces a severe competition from other bookmakers with different specialties. She cannot set the vig (commissions) freely, because bettors would simply walk away from bookmakers who charge higher vigs than others. She thus chooses her prices by maximizing her expected profits by taking the vig as given. 8 Meantime, in solving her problem, the bookmaker takes into account that her pricing decisions affect bettors demands for her bets. 9 The aggregate demand for her bets will increase in the ratio ˆp/q, where ˆp is the subjective probability of the outcome perceived by the betting public, and q is the corresponding probability implied by the betting price (odds-implied probability). This simple model allows us to draw a few 7 Examples of empirical studies on European football betting markets include Pope and Peel (1989), Cain, David and Peel (2000), Goddard and Asimakopoulos (2004), Deschamps and Gergaud (2007), Page (2009), Palomino, Renneboog, and Zhang (2009), Vlastakis, Dotsis, and Markellos (2009), Franck, Verbeek, and Neuesch (2010), Koning (2012), Nyberg (2014), Polson and Stern (2014), Feng, Polson, and Xu (2016), and Andrikogiannopoulou and Papakonstantinou (2016a,2016b,2017), among many others. 8 In Shin s (1991,1992,1993) model, two bookmakers bid for the monopoly rights to the betting market in the first stage, and the one who submits the lower vig wins the bid and offer odds in the second stage. 9 Betting demands of non-insiders in Shin s (1991,1992,1993) model are exogenous and perfectly inelastic at the balanced-book level, as his model focuses on the adverse selection problem with insiders. We consider an elastic demand, as Suits (1979) finds that price elasticities of demand in horse-race betting markets are very high considerably in excess of unity. 4

6 interesting implications about the behavior of bookmaker-determined prices. First, a bookmaker s rational pricing induces the Favorite-Longshot Bias. That is, an odds-implied probability (q) tends to overstate the chance of winning by the Longshot (that has a lower probability to win) and understate the chance of winning by the Favorite (that has a higher probability to win). This implication corroborates Shin s (1991,1992,1993) insight that bookmakers pricing decisions are at the origin of the Favorite-Longshot Bias, which is further supported by Bruce and Johnson s (2000) evidence that the Favorite- Longshot Bias exists only in bookmaker-based betting markets but not in Pari-mutuel betting markets for UK horse-races for which both forms of betting are available. Bettors misperceptions of probabilities, as suggested by the prospect theory (Tversky and Kahneman, 1992), are not suffi cient to generate the Favorite-Longshot Bias, though they can exacerbate the bias. Second, when bettors subjective probabilities are biased, bookmakers partially accommodate the biases in their pricing to exploit bettors demands. If a bookmaker were a pure monopolist and could set the vig freely, her pricing would disregard the bettors biases completely and rely only on her rational probabilistic assessments of the game outcomes. Faced with fierce competition, however, each bookmaker accommodates bettors biases partially in a manner that maximizes her expected profits under the vig constraint. 10 Third, increased competitions prompt each bookmaker to reinforce the Favorite-Longshot Bias and to distort prices to accommodate bettors biases further. Therefore, increased competitions tend to sustain, rather than suppress, biases in bookmaker-determined prices. Applying a log-linear approximation (Campbell and Shiller, 1988a,1988b) to the firstorder condition for the bookmaker s optimal price-setting, we cast our model into a tractable 10 This result is broadly consistent with Pope and Peel s (1989) and Levitt s (2004) findings that bookmakers optimally exploit bettors biases and maximize their profits by setting prices between the effi cient prices and those at which the book is balanced. Andrikogiannopoulou and Papakonstantinou (2017) note that the optimal price-setting behavior is in line with the actual practice of a bookmaker who provided their data. 5

7 multinomial logit model. We then implement the model in a sample of about 120, 000 soccer matches on Football-Data.co.uk between and Evidence for the Favorite- Longshot Bias is very strong and prevalent across leagues and over time. We also find evidence for a significant Hot-Hand Bias, but not for a Gambler s Fallacy. 12 That is, oddsimplied probabilities (q) tend to overstate the chance of winnings of teams with strong winning records, and understate the chance of winnings of teams with weak records. This evidence is broadly consistent with Andrikogiannopoulou and Papakonstantinou s (2017) finding that nearly 80% of individual bettors systematically overweigh (underweigh) teams on long winning (losing) streaks in European football betting markets. The Hot-Hand Bias generates a reversal effect (e.g. DeBondt and Thaler,1985) in betting returns, similarly to Moskowitz s (2015) finding of a value (reversal) effect in US sports betting markets, which he attributes to the bettors overreaction to information about game outcomes. 13 To complement the multinomial logit analysis, we examine the economic significance and time consistency of the two biases by constructing two hypothetical long-short portfolios. 14 The first portfolio aims to exploit the Favorite-Longshot Bias by taking a long position in bets with high prices (low odds) and a shot position in bets with low prices (high odds). The second portfolio aims to exploit the Hot-Hand Bias by taking a long position in bets on teams with weak betting returns and a short position in bets on teams with strong betting 11 We also conduct our analysis separately using a sample of about 22, 000 matches played in the Top Four European Football league divisions (England Premier League, German Bundesliga, Italian Serie A, Spanish La Liga). We use the Top Four Leagues to focus on the most active segments of the European football betting markets (similar to a Large Cap universe in stock markets). 12 The Hot-Hand Bias refers to the belief in positive autocorrelation of a non-autocorrelated random sequence, and the Gambler s Fallacy refers to the belief in negative autocorrelation of a non-autocorrelated random sequence. Our model can also capture the Home-Away Bias (over-betting on home-area teams) in the intercept term, but this term may capture other unknown effects and we refrain from discussing it. 13 Moskowitz (2015) examines how point spreads change between the Open, Close, and End (game outcome) of the betting and finds a momentum pattern between the Open and the Close, which is then reversed almost completely between the Close and the End. See also Gandar, Dare, Brown, and Zuber (1998) and Avery and Chevalier (1999) for earlier studies that examine the path of betting prices. 14 This exercise is hypothetical because one cannot short bookmakers odds in practice. 6

8 returns. Both hypothetical portfolio strategies would have produced positive long-short return spreads significantly and consistently between August 2000 and May The significant effects of the two biases do not show any signs of deterioration in the sample period despite the rapid growth and developments in European football betting markets, especially on the internet. This finding is diffi cult to reconcile with models that rely solely on bettor irrationality by ignoring the role of bookmakers, but it is consistent with the predicted price-setting behavior of bookmakers in response to increased competitions. 15 Comparing the two biases, the Favorite-Longshot Bias has been larger and more consistent than the Hot-Hand Bias, though the Hot-Hand Bias has also been significant. However, the Favorite-Longshot Bias stems primarily from a rational pricing behavior of bookmakers in the specific structure of betting markets ( Rational Mispricing ), and hence it provides little insights into financial market anomalies. The Hot-Hand Bias, on the other hand, derives from a fallacious belief of the betting public ( Irrational Mispricing ), which may have implications for the reversal in financial asset returns (e.g., Rabin and Vayanos, 2010). Still, it is worth noting that the presence and significance of the Hot-Hand Bias depend on the bookmakers rational decision to accommodate bettors biases in their prices. In sum, studies of market effi ciency in sports betting markets do not necessarily escape the joint hypothesis problem because their conclusions depend on how we account for the price-setting behavior of bookmakers. This paper demonstrates that a simple model of monopolistically competitive bookmakers can explain the prevalence and persistence of the Favorite-Longshot Bias and the Hot-Hand Bias in European football betting markets. Observed biases in bookmaker-determined prices may be largely affected by the price-setting decisions of bookmakers given a specific structure of sports betting markets, and hence may 15 Oikonomidis, Bruce, and Johnson (2015) document that a significant Favorite-Long Shot Bias prevails even in highly transparent internet-based European football betting markets. Puzzled by the finding, they conclude that markets may invariably be susceptible to fundamental risk evaluation problems. Our empirical results are consistent with theirs, but we attribute the findings to the price-setting behavior of bookmakers. 7

9 not be readily applicable to the discussion of financial market effi ciency. The rest of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 introduces our model of Fixed- Odds Betting markets and motivates our empirical hypotheses. Section 3 presents data and empirical results. Section 4 concludes. 2 A Model of Fixed-Odds Betting Markets 2.1 Nomenclature and Notation Fixed-Odds Betting System vs. Point-Spread Betting System The traditional form of the European football (soccer) betting market is characterized by the Fixed-Odds Betting system, whereas the traditional form of the US NFL and NBA betting markets is the Point-Spread Betting system. 16 In the Point-Spread Betting system, a bookmaker offers a point spread or a handicap. 17 For example, the bookmaker quotes Home Team 2.5 and Away team This means that a bet on the Home Team will win the bet if the Home Team defeats the Away Team by 3 points or more. However, a bet on the Home Team will lose the bet even when the Home Team defeats the Away Team, if the point difference is 1 or 2 points. In a Fixed-Odds Betting for a soccer match, each bookmaker announces her odds a few days before the match is played. Bookmakers offer Fixed-Odds against each of three possible outcomes of the match, which we index by j = 1, 0, 1: the Home Team Win (j = 1), Draw 16 Fixed-Odds Betting system and Point-Spread Betting system are very different from the Pari-mutuel Betting system in which odds are proportional to quantities of money wagered. In the Pari-mutuel Betting system, bookmakers can make money from the vigs regardless of the game outcomes. 17 MLB and NHL betting markets do not use the Point-Spread Betting system because scores in baseball and ice hockey matches tend to be much lower than those in American football or basketball games. MLB and NHL betting markets employ an odds or money line that resembles the Fixed Odds Betting system, though there are a few differences in rules and conventions. See Woodland and Woodland (1994) for a study of MLB betting markets. 8

10 (j = 0), or Away Team Win (j = 1). 18 This system allows each better to make a detailed comparison between the probability of an outcome implied by the Fixed-Odds and his own assessment of the probability before making his wagering decisions Betting Odds If an odd for the j-th outcome is R j, a successful bet with a size of one yields a payoff of R j and a profit of R j 1 (when the j-th outcome obtains). R j, j = 1, 0, 1, is the outcome-contingent dividend on a unit bet on the j-th outcome. We can also view R j as the gross return (one plus return) of a bet. For instance, betting on an outcome with the odds R j = 3.3 will turn a 1 bet into 3.3, 19 implying a return of 230% if the bet is successful (the j-th outcome obtains); and into nothing ( 0) with a return of 100% if the bet is unsuccessful Betting Prices and the Vig From an investor s perspective, the market for bets in a football match corresponds to a market for contingent claims with three states of the world, j = 1, 0, 1. We can think of state-contingent claims (Arrow-Debreu securities) which pay 1 if the j-th state outcome obtains and nothing otherwise, and have their prices determined by Q i = 1/R j, j = 1, 0, 1. The bookmaker offers odds on all three states, so our analysis rules out incomplete markets. Q i is the state price for the j-th outcome. We may simply call it the betting price of the j-th outcome. The sum of the state prices of all outcomes, 1 j= 1 Q j, gives the price of a portfolio that pays 1 for sure at the end of the match (regardless of the outcome). This 18 Although more complicated bets can be placed on the score or on the half-time and full-time results, we will focus on the simplest formulation of the bet. There are papers that focus on econometric predictions of football scores (and hence game outcomes). Examples include Dixon and Coles (1997), Goddard and Asimakopoulos (2004) and Feng, Polson, and Xu (2016), though modeling football scores is outside the scope of this study. 19 This can be a Dollar, Euro, etc. 9

11 amount is larger than 1 because bookmakers charge vigs (profit margins) in offering the bets. Thus, we can write 1 j= 1 Q j = 1 + v, where v > 0 is the vig Objective, Subjective, and Odds-Implied Probabilities We can also define the normalized state prices of the three outcomes by q j = Q j /( 1 k= 1 Q k) = Q j / (1 + v), so that 1 j= 1 q j = 1, q j (0, 1) for j = 1, 0, 1. We can interpret q j as the odds-implied probability of the j-th outcome reflected in the bookmaker s odd (j = 1, 0, 1). Although several studies interpret the odds-implied probability as the market s subjective probability for each outcome, this interpretation would be possible only when the books are balanced (Woodland and Woodland, 1994). Because bookmakers can influence the implied probability q j, we distinguish it from the subjective probability of the betting public, ˆp j (0, 1), j = 1, 0, 1, 1 j= 1 ˆp j = 1. We use p o j (0, 1) to denote the objective (actual) probability of each outcome, j = 1, 0, 1, 1 j= 1 po j = 1. The ratio ˆp j/p o j captures the bias in the subjective probability ˆp j. For example, ˆp j /p o j > 1 implies that the subjective probability overstates the chance of the j-th outcome and ˆp j /p o j < 1 implies that the subjective probability understates the chance of the j-th outcome. 2.2 Biases in Betting Markets and Their Possible Relations with Financial Markets The Hot-Hand Bias and the Gambler s Fallacy Several studies suggest that investors subjective probabilities (ˆp j ) deviate from the corresponding objective probabilities (p o j ) in a systematic manner, and the biases are correlated with certain characteristics of the players/teams in the matches. According to an influential study by Gilovich, Vallone, and Tversky (1985), most individuals watching basketball believe in the Hot-Hand : they tend to believe that players who make a shot are more 10

12 likely to hit the next shot than players who miss a shot. Put differently, most individuals believe in a positive auto-correlation in basketball shots though outcomes of consecutive shots are close to independent, or slightly negatively auto-correlated (Gilovich, Vallone, and Tversky s, 1985). Camerer (1989) studies US NBA (basketball) betting markets and finds that teams with winning streaks tend to do worse than expected (by point spreads), consistent with the Hot-Hand Bias. While the Hot-Hand bias refers to the belief in positive serial-correlation of a nonserially correlated random sequence, the belief in negative serial-correlation of a non-serially correlated random sequence is called the Gambler s Fallacy (e.g. Clotfelter and Cook, 1993, Terrell, 1994). Gambler s Fallacy derives from a fallacious belief that a small sample should resemble closely the underlying population, which is often referred to as the Law of Small Numbers or Local Representativeness bias (e.g. Rabin 2002). If individuals are prone to the Hot-Hand Bias and/or the Gambler s Fallacy, both betting returns and asset returns would exhibit return reversal effects (Jagadeesh and Titman, 1993) and/or return momentum effects (DeBondt and Thaler, 1985), respectively (Rabin and Vayanos, 2010). Since risk premiums play very little role in sports betting markets, return reversal and momentum effects in sports betting markets, if any, may reflect bettors biases in assessing probabilities. Our model explicitly allows for the possibility of these biases in bettors subjective probabilities. As Camerer (1989), Rabin (2002), and Rabin and Vayanos (2010) note, the Hot-Hand Bias does not necessarily contradict with the Gambler s Fallacy, as the Hot-Hand Bias may arise from the consequence of the Gambler s Fallacy. Although individuals tend to exhibit the Law of Small Numbers (the Gambler s Fallacy) after observing a short sequence of outcomes, they tend to believe in a Hot-Hand after observing long streaks (e.g. Edwards, 1961). Rabin and Vayanos (2010) develop a model in which agents exhibit a Gambler s Fallacy in the short-run but a Hot-Hand Bias in the long-run, which they associate with 11

13 return momentum effects in a relatively short horizon and return reversal effects in a long horizon The Favorite-Longshot Bias The Favorite-Longshot Bias refers to an observation that odds-implied probabilities (q) overstate the chance of winning by the Longshot (that has a lower probability to win) and understate the winning by the Favorite (that has a higher probability to win). The following, due to Shin (1991,1992,1993), provides a precise definition of the Favorite-Longshot Bias: Definition 1 Odds-implied probabilities (q) exhibit a Favorite-Longshot Bias when q j /q i < p o j /po i if and only if po j > po i, for i, j = 1, 0, 1, i j. In stock markets, the Favorite-Longshot Bias resembles the phenomenon that stocks with greater skewness tend to have lower returns ( negative skewness premium ). 20 Not surprisingly, both the Favorite-Longshot Bias and the negative skewness premium receive similar theoretical explanations. For example, Golec and Tamarkin (1995,1998) and Garrett and Sobel. (1999) argue that the Favorite-Longshot Bias is consistent with some individuals skewness preferences. Mitton and Vorkink (2007) also emphasize the role of some investors skewness preferences in explaining the negative skewness premium in stock markets. They show that investors with greater demand for positive skewness will consciously choose to remain under-diversified because diversification is a two-edged sword: it eliminates undesired variance in return distributions, but also eliminates desired skewness (p.1256). Julien and Selanie (2000) and Snowbert and Wolfers (2010) argue that the Favorite- Longshot Bias is consistent with bettors misperceptions of probabilities, as suggested by the prospect theory (Kahneman and Tversky, 1979, Tversky and Kahneman, 1992).and 20 See Mitton and Vorkink (2007), Brunnermeier, Gollier, and Park (2007), Barberis and Huang (2008), and Amaya, Christoffersen, Jacobs, and Vasquez (2015), among others. 12

14 implemented with a probability weighting function. In explaining the negative skewness premium, Barberis and Huang (2008) develop a model with cumulative prospecting investors who are more unhappy for downside risk than happy about upside potential. They show that, under the cumulative prospect theory preferences of Tversky and Kahneman (1992), investors transform objective probabilities using a weighting function that overweighs the tails of the probability distribution, and this causes positively skewed securities to become over-priced and to earn negative average risk-adjusted returns. From a similar but different angle, Brunnermeier, Gollier, and Park (2007) argue that investors tend to overstate the probabilities of large upside potential, because a small optimistic bias in beliefs typically leads to first-order gains in anticipatory utility and only second-order costs in realized outcomes (p.1092). In their model, investors optimize over beliefs of outcomes, as opposed to taking probabilities as given (Brunnermeier and Parker, 2005). This optimizing behavior of investors leads to, among other predictions, a strong preference for stocks with positively skewed distributions. This argument naturally extends to both the Favorite-Longshot Bias and the negative skewness premium. In our model, these theoretical effects affect bookmaker-determined prices though biases in bettors subjective probabilities (ˆp j ) and betting demands both of which are described below. In light of recent evidence on bettors; misperceptions of probabilities, our analysis will incorporate a probability weighting function that is suggested by Kahneman and Tversky (1992) and Camerer and Ho (1994). 2.3 Bookmakers Risk Exposure Bookmakers in the Fixed-Odds Betting and Point-Spread Betting systems can be exposed to a risk of losing money when the books do not balance. In the Point-Spread Betting system, a bookmaker can seek a point spread to balance the book, i.e., to balance the dollar amount wagered on each outcome. If the books are balanced, bookmakers can make money 13

15 regardless of the final game outcomes. We can thus view the market clearing spread as an expression of the dollar-weighted average opinion of the betting public (Camerer, 1989). In practice, bookmakers may choose wrong spreads to take speculative positions when they have superior information (Levitt, 2004). Bookmakers in the Fixed-Odds Betting system are in different situations. They can have large exposures to the risk of losing money, because odds are set before the match and are not adjusted to betting volumes. By way of example, let s consider a match in which there are only two outcomes, H (Home team win) and A (Away team win). To simplify matters, we ignore the vig (i.e., v = 0) and consider actuarially fair gambles. Suppose that 2/3 of the betting public (in terms of the quantity of money) bets on the outcome H and the remaining 1/3 bets on the outcome A. In this case, the actuarially fair odds are 1.5 for H and 3.0 for A. (H is the Favorite and A is the Longshot in this example.) Now suppose that the bookmaker fixes and announces the actuarially fair odds at 1.5 for H and 3.0 for A. In order for the bookmaker s book to balance, 2/3 of the wagers should go to H and 1/3 of the wagers should go to A. In this case, 1.5 2/3 and 3 1/3 always equal one, thus the bookmaker has no risk exposure. However, this balance hardly obtains because both bets have exactly the same expected return. Risk neutral bettors would be indifferent between the two bets, and hence it is more likely that similar amounts of wagers are placed on the two outcomes rather than they are allocated according to the respective probabilities (2/3 for H and 1/3 for A). When equal dollar amounts are wagered on both outcomes, bookmakers would lose money when the outcome A obtains (1 3 1/2 = 0.50), while they can earn profits when the outcome H obtains ( /2 = +0.25). As this simple example illustrates, bookmakers in Fixed-Odds Betting markets may end up taking large exposures to game outcomes even when they offered actuarially fair gambles. 14

16 2.4 Model Setup Bettors Subjective Probabilities The majority of existing studies do not distinguish between the implied probability q j and the subjective probability ˆp j. However, we explicitly consider possible biases in the subjective probability of the betting public (ˆp j ) and examine how the biases affect the implied probability (q j ). We consider two sources that can distort the subjective probability (ˆp j ) from the objective one (p o j ). The first source is the Hot-Hand Bias or the Gambler s Fallacy. We can incorporate the Hot-Hand Bias or the Gambler s Fallacy as follows. Let X j be the recent winning records of the Home team (j = 1) or the Away team (j = 1). We set X 0 = 0 for the Draw case. We then consider the following tractable specification of the subjective probability: ln ˆp j p j = X j δ + const j, for j = 1, 0, 1, (1) where p j is a reference probability which may be subject to the probability weighting in the prospect theory, as we describe below. const j is a constant term that plays no significant role in our analysis but ensures the subjective probabilities of the three outcomes to sum to one. X 1 (X 1 ) is higher when the Home (Away) team has a stronger winning record in recent matches. The Hot-Hand Bias implies δ > 0 in (1), and the Gambler s Fallacy implies δ < 0 for j = 1 and j = 1. The sign of δ may depend on the length of winning records in the measurement of X j, as the literature suggests that the Gambler s Fallacy arises in the short run but the Hot-Hand Bias becomes dominant in the long-run (e.g. Rabin, 2002, Rabin and Vayanos, 2010). Although we focus on the Hot-Hand Bias and the Gambler s Fallacy, due to their close association with the return reversal and momentum effects in financial markets, we can include a set of other team characteristics in X j when we hypothesize them to affect the subjective probability of the betting public. The second source of the bias in the subjective probability is the misperception of prob- 15

17 abilities as summarized by the probability weighting function in the prospect theory of Tversky and Kahneman (1992). Recent studies demonstrate the relevance of the prospect theory, especially the significance of probability weighting, in characterizing the wagering behavior of bettors (e.g. Julien and Selanie, 2000, Snowbert and Wolfers, 2010, Andrikogiannopoulou and Papakonstantinou, 2016a,2016b,2017). To model the probability weighting, we assume that the reference probability p j takes the following form, which is suggested by Tversky and Kahneman (1992) and Camerer and Ho (1994). 21 p j = (p o j )1 ε [ 1 ] 1, j = 1, 0, 1. (2) i= 1 (po i )1 ε 1 ε The prospect theory typically assumes ε [0, 1] to promote the idea that bettors tend to overreact to small probability events, but underreact to large probabilities (i.e., the Favorite-Longshot Bias). When ε = 0, p j is the same as the objective probability p o j. A larger deviation of ε from zero toward one implies a larger distortion of p j from p o j. The two equations (1) and (2) imply the following relation between a log odds-ratio of the subjective probabilities of the betting public ( ˆp) and that of the objective probabilities (p j ): ln ˆp j ˆp i = (1 ε) ln po j p o i + (X j X i ) δ + const, for i, j = 1, 0, 1, i j, (3) where const does not play an important role. In (3), δ > 0 (or δ > 0) captures the Hot- Hand Bias (or the Gambler s Fallacy). ε > 0 is consistent with the Favorite-Longshot Bias, according to the definition in Section Barberis and Huang (2008) consider a two-parameter asymmetric probability weighting function in a model with cumulative prospect theory, but this study focuses on a single parameter case. 16

18 2.4.2 Betting Demands Bettors subjective probabilities affect the aggregate demand. We consider the following specification of the aggregate betting demand for the j-th outcome (j = 1, 0, 1). ( ) η ˆpj x j (ˆp j, q j ) = for j = 1, 0, 1, (4) q j where η > 0 is the elasticity of demand with respect to the betting price per perceived chance, q/ ˆp. Suits (1979) reports that the elasticity η is in excess of unity in horserace betting markets. The form of the demand function (4) appears frequently in the macroeconomics literature with monopolistic competition (e.g., Dixit and Stiglitz, 1977). It describes that bettors tend to wager more (less) when expected return of the bet, according to their subjective probabilities, ˆp j R j = ˆp j /Q j, is higher. The benchmark case is when the implied probability and the subjective probability coincide, i.e., when q j = ˆp j. In this case, we assume that the aggregate amount wagered on the bet is one. The demand function (4) is a reduced-form specification of aggregate betting demands that is consistent with the demand of a representative bettor who maximizes 1 j= 1 (ˆp jx j R j 1 ρ xρ j ) ignoring the vig, where ρ = η > 1. This bettor maximizes his anticipated payoff (ignoring the vig), 1 j= 1 ˆp jx j R j, after subtracting a convex betting cost, 1 j= 1 xρ j, ρ > 1, that penalizes concentrated bets on particular game outcomes. We are not proposing this particular objective function as a model of bettors wagering decisions, but we can give a simple economic interpretation to the aggregate demand function (4). Being a reducedform demand function, it is not meant to model interactions of bettors with different risk preferences, heterogeneous probabilistic beliefs, and varying budgets. As Manski (2006) notes, however, aggregate demands should depend on the joint distribution of preferences, beliefs, and budgets across agents. For example, the literature has suggested locally convex utilities, skewness preferences, prospect theories with probability weighting functions, etc. to explain bettors wagering decisions, while Ali (1977) and 17

19 Gandhi and Serrano-Padial (2015) stress the importance of the heterogeneity in bettors subjective probabilities. The list can go on, but the literature is yet to agree on a standard model that can be used to aggregate individual bettors wagering decisions to generate a tractable aggregate betting demand. 22 Therefore, this study assumes a tractable singleparameter aggregate betting demand that allows us to focus on the price-setting behavior of monopolistically competitive bookmakers. Specifically, the single parameter η captures the elasticity of the aggregate betting demand. The elasticity parameter η increases when different bets (e.g. bets on Real Madrid, Bayern Münich, Chelsea, Juventus, etc.) become closer substitutes, i.e., when each bet becomes closer to financial securities. We expect η to increase with the institutional and technological developments of the markets and with the number of professional bettors and information service providers. Thus, we take the liberty of interpreting η as a measure of market sophistication in sports betting markets. In perfectly competitive securities markets, η tends to infinity The Bookmaker s Problem Each bookmaker is more skilled in assessing the probability of each game outcome than others (Levitt, 2004). In our model, the bookmaker is rational in a sense that she employs the objective probability p o j (j = 1, 0, 1) in setting her odds for each outcome. Since risks associated with betting outcomes are idiosyncratic and diversifiable across matches, we assume that each bookmaker is risk-neutral, similarly to Shin (1991,1992,1993). The risk-neutral bookmaker s problem is to maximize her expected profit by setting Q j 22 More recently, Andrikogiannopoulou and Papakonstantinou (2016a,2016b,2017) analyze a unique dataset of wagering activities by 500 randomly selected individuals in European sports betting markets. Their studies point to the relevance of the prospect theory, especially the significance of probability weighting, in characterizing bettors risk preferences and betting demands. They abstract away from bookmakers pricesetting behavior, however. Thus, their focus on individuals betting demands and our focus on bookmakers price-setting decisions are complementary. 18

20 for the three possible outcomes (j = 1, 0, 1): max E[Π] = {Q j } j=1,0, 1 1 j= 1 x j (ˆp j, q j ) 1 j= 1 p o jx j (ˆp j, q j ) 1 Q j, (5) subject to the vig constraint, 1 j= 1 Q j = 1 + v, where ˆp j (0, 1), p o j (0, 1), and Q j (0, 1 + v). The demand function x j (ˆp j, q j ) is given in (4) with q j = Q j / (1 + v). We focus on the interior solution and preclude the unrealistic cases of q j = 0 (R j ) or q j = 1 (R j = 1/ (1 + v) < 1) Monopolistic Competition among Bookmakers If the bookmaker had no vig constraint, the unconstrained solution to her optimization problem would be Q j = (1 + 1 η )po j, j = 1, 0, 1, implying 1 j= 1 Q j = η. Thus the optimal vig (markup) of the monopolist would be v = 1 η. Q j (j = 1, 0, 1) is the optimal price if the bookmaker were a pure monopolist who could set the vig freely. In practice, each bookmaker can exert her market power only within her specialized segment, and the vig is determined by competitive forces in the bookmaking market. Since bettors are free to walk away from high-vig betting opportunities for low-vig betting opportunities, each bookmaker has to take the level of vig (v < 1 η ) as given. We introduce θ = 1 ηv as a measure of the degree of monopolistic competition among bookmakers. Note that v = (1 θ) /η = (1 θ) v where v is the vig level chosen by a pure monopolist. Pure monopoly would imply θ = 0, but the vig level will decrease with θ. That is, a higher value of θ (0, 1) implies that more intense competition among bookmakers. With the monopolistic competition, the bookmaker has to offer betting prices that are ) lower than the monopolistic prices, and hence Q j < Q j or q j/p o j (1 < + 1 η / (1 + v) for j = 1, 0, 1. 19

21 2.5 Model Implications The first-order condition for the optimality given the constraint 1 j= 1 Q j = 1 + v (or 1 j= 1 q j = 1) and possible biases in bettors subjective probabilities (3) implies the following identity expressed in terms of odds ratios : 23 η ln ˆp j (1 + η) ln q 1+ 1 η p o j j 1+v q + ln j 1 = 0, for i, j = 1, 0, 1, i j. (6) ˆp i q i 1+ 1 η p o i 1+v q i 1 The assumption that the bookmaker has to offer betting prices lower than the monopolistic ) prices (i.e., Q j < Q j and hence q j/p o j (1 < + 1 η / (1 + v)) ensures that the term inside the square bracket in (6) is positive. This condition also satisfies the second-order condition, ) q j /p o j (1 < + 2 η / (1 + v) for j = 1, 0, 1. The first-order condition (6) is nonlinear and diffi cult to interpret. To obtain useful empirical predictions, we apply the log-linear approximation of Campbell and Shiller (1988a,1988b) around p o j /q j = 1 for j = 1, 0, 1. Proposition 1 Let p o j be the objective probability of the j-th game outcome, j = 1, 0, 1, which the bookmaker uses. Let ˆp j denote the subjective probability of the betting public for the same outcome, where the log odds ratio ln ˆp j ˆp i is characterized by the relation (3). Then, solutions to the bookmaker s constrained optimization problem (5) should satisfy the following approximate identity: where ln q j q i γ ln po j p o i + (X j X i ) δφ + const, for i, j = 1, 0, 1, i j, (7) θ (1 + ηε) γ = 1 + η + ηθ(1 ε), (8) ηθ φ = (1 + η) (1 + θ) (9) with θ = 1 ηv (0, 1) capturing the degree of monopolistic competition. In (7), const is a constant term that plays no significant role in our analysis. 23 Odds ratio here is a statistical/econometric terminology referring to the ratio of two probabilities. The meaning of odds here is different from betting odds. 20

22 In the case of a pure monopoly (θ = 0), both γ and φ become zero and the odds-implied probability q j would reveal the bookmaker s superior assessment of the objective probability p o j fully for j = 1, 0, 1. That is, when the bookmaker could set the vig freely to maximize her expected profits, her pricing would reveal her superior probabilistic assessments of the game outcomes, regardless of the Hot-Hand Bias, the Gambler s Fallacy, or the probability weighting. In another extreme case of perfectly inelastic betting demand (i.e., η 0), θ tends to one and hence we would have γ = 1 and φ = 0. That is, a square root pricing rule that resembles Shin s (1991) obtains. This would not be surprising because Shin (1991) assumes exogenous and perfectly inelastic betting demands. In practice, aggregate betting demands are elastic (η > 0), and bookmakers face competition from other bookmakers and potential entrants, θ (0, 1). In this practical setting, the log approximate identity (7) yields a few interesting implications: First, γ is positive, meaning that a Favorite-Longshot Bias obtains according to the definition in Section The Favorite-Longshot Bias (γ > 0) arises even in the absence of bettor irrationality (δ = 0 and ε = 0). The Favorite-Longshot Bias is thus driven by the bookmaker s optimal price setting behavior under monopolistic competition, and it represents the Rational Mispricing in sports betting markets. Our model implies that bookmakers pricing decisions are at the origin of the Favorite-Longshot Bias. This implication is similar to Shin s (1991,1992,1993) result, but our model does not assume the presence of insiders (bettors who have inside information about the game outcomes). This implication is also consistent with the empirical evidence of Bruce and Johnson (2000) who show that the Favorite-Longshot Bias exists only in bookmaker-based betting markets but not in Pari-mutuel betting markets for UK horse-races for which both forms of betting are available. We also note that γ increases with ε, meaning that bettors misperceptions of probabilities, along the line of the prospect theory (Tversky and Kahneman, 1992), can exacerbate 21

23 the Favorite-Longshot Bias. However, the probability weighting alone does not lead to the Favorite-Longshot Bias. Monopolistic competition among bookmakers (θ > 0) is necessary and the Favorite-Longshot Bias (γ > 0) is consistent with the rational price-setting behavior of the bookmakers. A higher demand elasticity (η) and a larger misperception of probabilities (ε) tend to make the Favorite-Longshot Bias larger. Second, even when bettors subjective probabilities exhibit biases (e.g. the Hot-Hand Bias and/or the Gambler s Fallacy), the bookmaker s optimal price setting eliminates more than half of the biases, as φ (0, 1 2 ). However, the bookmaker will not correct the biases completely, because she can take advantage of bettors demands by accommodating their biases in order to maximize her expected profits. Thus, Irrational Mispricing in bookmaker-determined prices arise from bettor s biases. Third, for a given level of elasticity (or sophistication of the betting market) η, the degree of Rational Mispricing (γ) increases with the degree of monopolistic competition among bookmakers, θ. Also for a given level of elasticity η and bettors biases δ, the degree of Irrational Mispricing (δφ) increases with the degree of monopolistic competition, θ, as φ is increasing in θ. That is, as the competition among bookmakers gets more intense, the degree of Rational Mispricing and that of Irrational Mispricing increase, rather than decrease. Fourth, for a given level of θ, an increase in the elasticity of aggregate demands η, or the sophistication of the betting market, reduces the vig and the degree of the Favorite-Longshot Bias γ. This implication is consistent with the notion that each bookmaker s market power in her specialty declines as η increases, i.e., as the betting market gets closer to competitive securities markets. However, the relation between the vig and the Favorite-Longshot Bias is ambiguous, as a decline in the vig can be associated with either an increase in η or an increase in θ. That is, the Favorite-Longshot Bias (Rational Mispricing) does not necessarily decrease with a decline in the vig. On the other hand, φ increases with η, but δ is likely to 22

24 decrease with η. Thus, the relation between the betting market s sophistication (η) and the degree of Irrational Mispricing (δφ) is ambiguous. Even when the betting market gets more sophisticated, the degree of Irrational Mispricing does not necessarily decline, contrary to what we tend to anticipate. Among these four implications, the first two give unambiguous empirical predictions, and we cast these into empirical hypotheses below. The remaining two implications, while surprising and somewhat counter-intuitive, are diffi cult to test because we cannot observe the degree of competition among bookmakers (θ), that of market sophistication (η), or that of bettors biases (δ) directly. We only observe the vig, v = 1 θ η, which is decreasing in both θ and η. We thus ask how the recent growth in sports betting markets, as manifested by a steady decline in the vig, has been associated with the level of Rational Mispricing (γ) and that of Irrational Mispricing (δφ) in European football betting markets. 2.6 Empirical Hypotheses Main Hypotheses We can cast (7) naturally into a multinomial logit regression model, 24 which can be implemented in data without any ad hoc modifications. Specifically, using the Draw outcome (j = 0) as the pivot category and setting X 0 = 0, we can express the log odds ratios of the Home team win (j = 1) and the Away team win (j = 1) as: ln po 1 p o 0 = (1 + γ) ln q 1 q 0 X 1 β + a 1, ln po 1 p o 0 = (1 + γ) ln q 1 q 0 X 1 β + a 1, (10) where γ is given by equation (8) and β = δηθ 1 + η + ηθ (1 ε). 24 Former studies that use multinomial logit models in betting markets include Figlewski (1979), Vlastakis, Dotsis, Markellos (2009), and Nyberg (2014), among others. 23

25 a 1 and a 1 are constants whose difference may capture the Home-Away Bias. But we refrain from pushing this interpretation as these intercept terms may capture other effects. We implement the empirical model (10) with maximum likelihood to test the following hypotheses: Hypothesis 1 (Rational Mispricing) Bookmakers price-setting behavior in monopolistic competition induces a Favorite-Longshot Bias, γ > 0. The null hypothesis is γ = 0. Hypothesis 2 (Irrational Mispricing) The team s past performance can bias the subjective probabilities of the betting public and affects the odds-implied probabilities, after controlling for the Favorite-Longshot Bias, and hence β 0. β > 0 implies a Hot-Hand Bias whereas β < 0 implies a Gambler s Fallacy. The null hypothesis is β = 0. We use γ as a measure of Rational Mispricing because the Favorite-Longshot Bias arises from the bookmakers price setting behavior, even in the absence of bettors biases. Rational Mispricing is specific to the organizational structure of sports betting markets, and hence is not transferable to financial markets. The probability weighting, as suggested by the prospect theory (Tversky and Kahneman, 1992), can exacerbate the Favorite-Longshot Bias as γ increases with ε. However, the probability weighting ε > 0 is not suffi cient for the Favorite-Longshot Bias (γ > 0) to arise. Monopolistic competition among bookmakers θ > 0 plays a key role in the generation of the bias. On the other hand, we associate β with Irrational Mispricing as it is originated from biases in bettors subjective probabilities. For example, a return reversal (value) effects associated with the Hot-Hand Bias, if any, may help us understand similar effects in financial markets (Rabin and Vayanos, 2010). The probability weighting ε > 0 can again intensify the observed degree of Irrational Mispricing, as the absolute value of β increases with ε. 24

Gamblers Favor Skewness, Not Risk: Further Evidence from United States Lottery Games

Gamblers Favor Skewness, Not Risk: Further Evidence from United States Lottery Games Gamblers Favor Skewness, Not Risk: Further Evidence from United States Lottery Games Thomas A. Garrett Russell S. Sobel Department of Economics West Virginia University Morgantown, West Virginia 26506

More information

Using Actual Betting Percentages to Analyze Sportsbook Behavior: The Canadian and Arena Football Leagues

Using Actual Betting Percentages to Analyze Sportsbook Behavior: The Canadian and Arena Football Leagues Syracuse University SURFACE College Research Center David B. Falk College of Sport and Human Dynamics October 2010 Using Actual Betting s to Analyze Sportsbook Behavior: The Canadian and Arena Football

More information

Working Paper No

Working Paper No Working Paper No. 2010-05 Prices, Point Spreads and Profits: Evidence from the National Football League Brad R. Humphreys University of Alberta February 2010 Copyright to papers in this working paper series

More information

What Causes the Favorite-Longshot Bias? Further Evidence from Tennis

What Causes the Favorite-Longshot Bias? Further Evidence from Tennis MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive What Causes the Favorite-Longshot Bias? Further Evidence from Tennis Jiri Lahvicka 30. June 2013 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/47905/ MPRA Paper No. 47905,

More information

Sportsbook pricing and the behavioral biases of bettors in the NHL

Sportsbook pricing and the behavioral biases of bettors in the NHL Syracuse University SURFACE College Research Center David B. Falk College of Sport and Human Dynamics December 2009 Sportsbook pricing and the behavioral biases of bettors in the NHL Rodney Paul Syracuse

More information

Game, set and match: The favorite-long shot bias in tennis betting exchanges.

Game, set and match: The favorite-long shot bias in tennis betting exchanges. Game, set and match: The favorite-long shot bias in tennis betting exchanges. Isabel Abinzano, Luis Muga and Rafael Santamaria Public University of Navarre (SPAIN) June 2015 Abstract: We test for the existence

More information

Hot Hand or Invisible Hand: Which Grips the Football Betting Market?

Hot Hand or Invisible Hand: Which Grips the Football Betting Market? Hot Hand or Invisible Hand: Which Grips the Football Betting Market? Ladd Kochman Ken Gilliam David Bray Coles College of Business Kennesaw State University Hot Hand or Invisible Hand: Which Grips the

More information

Staking plans in sports betting under unknown true probabilities of the event

Staking plans in sports betting under unknown true probabilities of the event Staking plans in sports betting under unknown true probabilities of the event Andrés Barge-Gil 1 1 Department of Economic Analysis, Universidad Complutense de Madrid, Spain June 15, 2018 Abstract Kelly

More information

Market Efficiency and Behavioral Biases in the WNBA Betting Market

Market Efficiency and Behavioral Biases in the WNBA Betting Market Int. J. Financial Stud. 2014, 2, 193 202; doi:10.3390/ijfs2020193 Article OPEN ACCESS International Journal of Financial Studies ISSN 2227-7072 www.mdpi.com/journal/ijfs Market Efficiency and Behavioral

More information

Peer Reviewed. Abstract

Peer Reviewed. Abstract Peer Reviewed Richard A. Paulson rapaulson@stcloudstate.edu is a Professor in the Business Computer Information Systems Department, St. Cloud State University. Abstract Gambling markets have historically

More information

Individual Behavior and Beliefs in Parimutuel Betting Markets

Individual Behavior and Beliefs in Parimutuel Betting Markets Mini-Conference on INFORMATION AND PREDICTION MARKETS Individual Behavior and Beliefs in Parimutuel Betting Markets Frédéric KOESSLER University of Cergy-Pontoise (France) Charles NOUSSAIR Faculty of Arts

More information

BIASES IN ASSESSMENTS OF PROBABILITIES: NEW EVIDENCE FROM GREYHOUND RACES. Dek Terrell* August Abstract

BIASES IN ASSESSMENTS OF PROBABILITIES: NEW EVIDENCE FROM GREYHOUND RACES. Dek Terrell* August Abstract BIASES IN ASSESSMENTS OF PROBABILITIES: NEW EVIDENCE FROM GREYHOUND RACES Dek Terrell* August 1997 Abstract This paper investigates biases in the perceptions of probabilities using data from the 1989 and

More information

Information effects in major league baseball betting markets

Information effects in major league baseball betting markets Applied Economics, 2012, 44, 707 716 Information effects in major league baseball betting markets Matt E. Ryan a, *, Marshall Gramm b and Nicholas McKinney b a Department of Economics and Quantitative

More information

Deciding When to Quit: Reference-Dependence over Slot Machine Outcomes

Deciding When to Quit: Reference-Dependence over Slot Machine Outcomes Deciding When to Quit: Reference-Dependence over Slot Machine Outcomes By JAIMIE W. LIEN * AND JIE ZHENG * Lien: Department of Economics, School of Economics and Management, Tsinghua University, Beijing,

More information

Mathematics of Pari-Mutuel Wagering

Mathematics of Pari-Mutuel Wagering Millersville University of Pennsylvania April 17, 2014 Project Objectives Model the horse racing process to predict the outcome of a race. Use the win and exacta betting pools to estimate probabilities

More information

An exploration of the origins of the favourite-longshot bias in horserace betting markets

An exploration of the origins of the favourite-longshot bias in horserace betting markets An exploration of the origins of the favourite-longshot bias in horserace betting markets Alistair Bruce, Johnnie Johnson & Jiejun Yu Centre for Risk Research University of Southampton 1 University of

More information

In Search of Sure Things An Analysis of Market Efficiency in the NFL Betting Market

In Search of Sure Things An Analysis of Market Efficiency in the NFL Betting Market In Search of Sure Things An Analysis of Market Efficiency in the NFL Betting Market By: Rick Johnson Advisor: Professor Eric Schulz Submitted for Honors in Mathematical Methods in the Social Sciences Spring,

More information

Overreaction in Football Wagers

Overreaction in Football Wagers Overreaction in Football Wagers Gary Smith Department of Economics Pomona College Andrew Capron Department of Economics Pomona College Corresponding author: Gary Smith Department of Economics Pomona College

More information

Power-law distribution in Japanese racetrack betting

Power-law distribution in Japanese racetrack betting Power-law distribution in Japanese racetrack betting Takashi Ichinomiya Nonlinear Studies and Computation, Research Institute for Electronic Science, Hokkaido University, Sapporo 060-0812, Japan. Abstract

More information

A Failure of the No-Arbitrage Principle

A Failure of the No-Arbitrage Principle London School of Economics and Political Science From the SelectedWorks of Kristof Madarasz 2007 A Failure of the No-Arbitrage Principle Kristof Madarasz, London School of Economics and Political Science

More information

Why are Gambling Markets Organized so Differently than Financial Markets? *

Why are Gambling Markets Organized so Differently than Financial Markets? * Why are Gambling Markets Organized so Differently than Financial Markets? * Steven D. Levitt University of Chicago and American Bar Foundation slevitt@midway.uchicago.edu August 2003 * Department of Economics,

More information

Contingent Valuation Methods

Contingent Valuation Methods ECNS 432 Ch 15 Contingent Valuation Methods General approach to all CV methods 1 st : Identify sample of respondents from the population w/ standing 2 nd : Respondents are asked questions about their valuations

More information

The sentiment bias in the market for tennis betting

The sentiment bias in the market for tennis betting The sentiment bias in the market for tennis betting Saskia van Rheenen 347986 Behavioural Economics April 2017 Supervisor dr. T.L.P.R. Peeters Second reader dr. G.D. Granic TABLE OF CONTENTS List of Tables

More information

Does the Hot Hand Drive the Market? Evidence from Betting Markets

Does the Hot Hand Drive the Market? Evidence from Betting Markets Does the Hot Hand Drive the Market? Evidence from Betting Markets Michael Sinkey and Trevon Logan December 2011 Abstract This paper investigates how market makers respond to behavioral strategies and the

More information

High Bets for the Win?

High Bets for the Win? High Bets for the Win? The Role of Stake Size in Sports Betting Radek Janhuba & Jakub Mikulka (CERGE-EI) June 4, 2018 Latest version: http://www.radekjanhuba.com/files/rjjm_stakes.pdf Abstract We analyze

More information

Columbia University. Department of Economics Discussion Paper Series. Auctioning the NFL Overtime Possession. Yeon-Koo Che Terry Hendershott

Columbia University. Department of Economics Discussion Paper Series. Auctioning the NFL Overtime Possession. Yeon-Koo Che Terry Hendershott Columbia University Department of Economics Discussion Paper Series Auctioning the NFL Overtime Possession Yeon-Koo Che Terry Hendershott Discussion Paper No: 0506-25 Department of Economics Columbia University

More information

International Journal of Computer Science in Sport. Ordinal versus nominal regression models and the problem of correctly predicting draws in soccer

International Journal of Computer Science in Sport. Ordinal versus nominal regression models and the problem of correctly predicting draws in soccer International Journal of Computer Science in Sport Volume 16, Issue 1, 2017 Journal homepage: http://iacss.org/index.php?id=30 DOI: 10.1515/ijcss-2017-0004 Ordinal versus nominal regression models and

More information

Extreme Shooters in the NBA

Extreme Shooters in the NBA Extreme Shooters in the NBA Manav Kant and Lisa R. Goldberg 1. Introduction December 24, 2018 It is widely perceived that star shooters in basketball have hot and cold streaks. This perception was first

More information

The Cold Facts About the "Hot Hand" in Basketball

The Cold Facts About the Hot Hand in Basketball The Cold Facts About the "Hot Hand" in Basketball Do basketball players tend to shoot in streaks? Contrary to the belief of fans and commentators, analysis shows that the chances of hitting a shot are

More information

Racial Bias in the NBA: Implications in Betting Markets

Racial Bias in the NBA: Implications in Betting Markets Brigham Young University BYU ScholarsArchive All Faculty Publications 2008-04-01 Racial Bias in the NBA: Implications in Betting Markets Tim Larsen tlarsen@byu.net Joe Prince See next page for additional

More information

Tilburg University. Bets and Bids Potters, Jan; Wit, J. Publication date: Link to publication

Tilburg University. Bets and Bids Potters, Jan; Wit, J. Publication date: Link to publication Tilburg University Bets and Bids Potters, Jan; Wit, J. Publication date: 1996 Link to publication Citation for published version (APA): Potters, J. J. M., & Wit, J. (1996). Bets and Bids: Favorite-Longshot

More information

1. Answer this student s question: Is a random sample of 5% of the students at my school large enough, or should I use 10%?

1. Answer this student s question: Is a random sample of 5% of the students at my school large enough, or should I use 10%? Econ 57 Gary Smith Fall 2011 Final Examination (150 minutes) No calculators allowed. Just set up your answers, for example, P = 49/52. BE SURE TO EXPLAIN YOUR REASONING. If you want extra time, you can

More information

Professionals Play Minimax: Appendix

Professionals Play Minimax: Appendix Professionals Play Minimax: Appendix Ignacio Palacios-Huerta Brown University July 2002 In this supplementary appendix we first report additional descriptive statistics in section 1. We begin by reporting

More information

Behavior under Social Pressure: Empty Italian Stadiums and Referee Bias

Behavior under Social Pressure: Empty Italian Stadiums and Referee Bias Behavior under Social Pressure: Empty Italian Stadiums and Referee Bias Per Pettersson-Lidbom a and Mikael Priks bc* April 11, 2010 Abstract Due to tightened safety regulation, some Italian soccer teams

More information

Original Article. Correlation analysis of a horse-betting portfolio: the international official horse show (CSIO) of Gijón

Original Article. Correlation analysis of a horse-betting portfolio: the international official horse show (CSIO) of Gijón Journal of Physical Education and Sport (JPES), 18(Supplement issue 3), Art 191, pp.1285-1289, 2018 online ISSN: 2247-806X; p-issn: 2247 8051; ISSN - L = 2247-8051 JPES Original Article Correlation analysis

More information

Revisiting the Hot Hand Theory with Free Throw Data in a Multivariate Framework

Revisiting the Hot Hand Theory with Free Throw Data in a Multivariate Framework Calhoun: The NPS Institutional Archive DSpace Repository Faculty and Researchers Faculty and Researchers Collection 2010 Revisiting the Hot Hand Theory with Free Throw Data in a Multivariate Framework

More information

Forecasting sports tournaments by ratings of (prob)abilities

Forecasting sports tournaments by ratings of (prob)abilities Forecasting sports tournaments by ratings of (prob)abilities Achim Zeileis, Christoph Leitner, Kurt Hornik http://eeecon.uibk.ac.at/~zeileis/ UEFA Euro 2016 prediction Source: UEFA, Wikipedia UEFA Euro

More information

Existence of Nash Equilibria

Existence of Nash Equilibria Existence of Nash Equilibria Before we can prove the existence, we need to remind you of the fixed point theorem: Kakutani s Fixed Point Theorem: Consider X R n a compact convex set and a function f: X

More information

Determinants of NFL Spread Pricing:

Determinants of NFL Spread Pricing: Determinants of NFL Spread Pricing: Incorporation of Google Search Data Over the Course of the Gambling Week Shiv S. Gidumal and Roland D. Muench Under the supervision of Dr. Emma B. Rasiel Dr. Michelle

More information

Racetrack Betting: Do Bettors Understand the Odds?

Racetrack Betting: Do Bettors Understand the Odds? University of Pennsylvania ScholarlyCommons Statistics Papers Wharton Faculty Research 1994 Racetrack Betting: Do Bettors Understand the Odds? Lawrence D. Brown University of Pennsylvania Rebecca D'Amato

More information

Is Home-Field Advantage Driven by the Fans? Evidence from Across the Ocean. Anne Anders 1 John E. Walker Department of Economics Clemson University

Is Home-Field Advantage Driven by the Fans? Evidence from Across the Ocean. Anne Anders 1 John E. Walker Department of Economics Clemson University Is Home-Field Advantage Driven by the Fans? Evidence from Across the Ocean Anne Anders 1 John E. Walker Department of Economics Clemson University Kurt W. Rotthoff Stillman School of Business Seton Hall

More information

Extensive Games with Perfect Information

Extensive Games with Perfect Information Extensive Games with Perfect Information A strategic situation in which players play a game over time. At the point of making the decision, players are informed about the action chosen before by the others.

More information

EFFICIENCY OF RACETRACK BETTING MARKETS. editors. Donald B Hausch. University of Wisconsin-Madison, USA. Victor SY Lo

EFFICIENCY OF RACETRACK BETTING MARKETS. editors. Donald B Hausch. University of Wisconsin-Madison, USA. Victor SY Lo EFFICIENCY OF RACETRACK BETTING MARKETS 2008 Edition editors Donald B Hausch University of Wisconsin-Madison, USA Victor SY Lo University of British Columbia, Canada William TZiemba University of British

More information

Game Theory (MBA 217) Final Paper. Chow Heavy Industries Ty Chow Kenny Miller Simiso Nzima Scott Winder

Game Theory (MBA 217) Final Paper. Chow Heavy Industries Ty Chow Kenny Miller Simiso Nzima Scott Winder Game Theory (MBA 217) Final Paper Chow Heavy Industries Ty Chow Kenny Miller Simiso Nzima Scott Winder Introduction The end of a basketball game is when legends are made or hearts are broken. It is what

More information

Inter-Market Arbitrage in Betting *

Inter-Market Arbitrage in Betting * Inter-Market Arbitrage in Betting * Egon Franck, Erwin Verbeek, Stephan Nüesch forthcoming in Economica (Version: January 2012) We show that a combined bet at the bookmaker and at the bet exchange market

More information

A Game Theoretic Study of Attack and Defense in Cyber-Physical Systems

A Game Theoretic Study of Attack and Defense in Cyber-Physical Systems The First International Workshop on Cyber-Physical Networking Systems A Game Theoretic Study of Attack and Defense in Cyber-Physical Systems ChrisY.T.Ma Advanced Digital Sciences Center Illinois at Singapore

More information

Quantitative Methods for Economics Tutorial 6. Katherine Eyal

Quantitative Methods for Economics Tutorial 6. Katherine Eyal Quantitative Methods for Economics Tutorial 6 Katherine Eyal TUTORIAL 6 13 September 2010 ECO3021S Part A: Problems 1. (a) In 1857, the German statistician Ernst Engel formulated his famous law: Households

More information

Sport Hedge Millionaire s Guide to a growing portfolio. Sports Hedge

Sport Hedge Millionaire s Guide to a growing portfolio. Sports Hedge Sports Hedge Sport Hedging for the millionaire inside us, a manual for hedging and profiting for a growing portfolio Congratulations, you are about to have access to the techniques sports books do not

More information

All the Mail Pay instructions will be clearly printed on the back of your winning ticket!

All the Mail Pay instructions will be clearly printed on the back of your winning ticket! Propositions Proposition wagering (most commonly referred to as Props ) has become an increasingly popular betting option and all BetLucky Sportsbooks will offer a diverse variety of props every day. Futures

More information

Hot Hands and Equilibrium

Hot Hands and Equilibrium Hot Hands and Equilibrium By Gil Aharoni University of Melbourne Oded H. Sarig IDC, Herzeliya and The Wharton School First version: September 2005 This version: March 2007 Part of this research was conducted

More information

Skewness is the name of the game

Skewness is the name of the game Edith Cowan University Research Online ECU Publications Pre. 2011 2001 Skewness is the name of the game Y. H. Cheung Cheung, Y. (2001). Skewness is the name of the game. Joondalup, Australia: Edith Cowan

More information

Does Momentum Exist in Competitive Volleyball?

Does Momentum Exist in Competitive Volleyball? O Privacy, Where Art Thou Visual Revelations Editor's Letter Letters to the Editor Supplemental Material Articles Columns Goodness of Wit Test Here's to Your Health Does Momentum Exist in Competitive Volleyball?

More information

IS POINT SHAVING IN COLLEGE BASKETBALL WIDESPREAD?

IS POINT SHAVING IN COLLEGE BASKETBALL WIDESPREAD? UNC CHARLOTTE ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES IS POINT SHAVING IN COLLEGE BASKETBALL WIDESPREAD? Jason P. Berkowitz Craig A. Depken, II John M. Gandar Working Paper No. 2016-012 THE UNIVERSITY OF NORTH

More information

Learning about Banks Net Worth and the Slow Recovery after the Financial Crisis

Learning about Banks Net Worth and the Slow Recovery after the Financial Crisis Learning about Banks Net Worth and the Slow Recovery after the Financial Crisis Josef Hollmayr (Deutsche Bundesbank) and Michael Kühl (Deutsche Bundesbank) The presentation represents the personal opinion

More information

Are Longshots Only for Losers? A New Look at the Last Race Effect

Are Longshots Only for Losers? A New Look at the Last Race Effect Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, J. Behav. Dec. Making, 29: 25 36 (2016) Published online 29 March 2015 in Wiley Online Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com).1873 Are Longshots Only for Losers? A New

More information

Review of A Detailed Investigation of Crash Risk Reduction Resulting from Red Light Cameras in Small Urban Areas by M. Burkey and K.

Review of A Detailed Investigation of Crash Risk Reduction Resulting from Red Light Cameras in Small Urban Areas by M. Burkey and K. Review of A Detailed Investigation of Crash Risk Reduction Resulting from Red Light Cameras in Small Urban Areas by M. Burkey and K. Obeng Sergey Y. Kyrychenko Richard A. Retting November 2004 Mark Burkey

More information

When Betting Odds and Credences Come Apart: More Worries for Dutch Book Arguments

When Betting Odds and Credences Come Apart: More Worries for Dutch Book Arguments When Betting Odds and Credences Come Apart: More Worries for Dutch Book Arguments Darren BRADLEY and Hannes LEITGEB If an agent believes that the probability of E being true is 1/2, should she accept a

More information

Parametric Asset Allocation

Parametric Asset Allocation Parametric Asset Allocation Thomas Dangl, Arne Westerkamp, Josef Zechner April 19, 2013 VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE! We study how a simple asset allocation policy in which the investment weights are

More information

DOWNLOAD PDF TELEPHONE NUMBERS THAT PROVIDE THE WINNING NUMBERS FOR EACH LOTTERY.

DOWNLOAD PDF TELEPHONE NUMBERS THAT PROVIDE THE WINNING NUMBERS FOR EACH LOTTERY. Chapter 1 : Most Common Winning Lottery Numbers Are Not The Best Numbers In the event of a discrepancy between the information displayed on this website concerning winning numbers and prize payouts and

More information

JACKPOT PITFALLS IN EGM PLAYING: DETERMINISTIC OR PROGRESSIVE?

JACKPOT PITFALLS IN EGM PLAYING: DETERMINISTIC OR PROGRESSIVE? 1 JACKPOT PITFALLS IN EGM PLAYING: DETERMINISTIC OR PROGRESSIVE? En Li, Matthew Rockloff, Phillip Donaldson, Matthew Browne, and Erika Langham Experimental Gambling Research Laboratory, Central Queensland

More information

Annual results 2017 and strategy update. 09 March 2018

Annual results 2017 and strategy update. 09 March 2018 Annual results 2017 and strategy update 09 March 2018 Agenda 1. Highlights & Group performance 2017 2. Strategy update 3. Outlook 2018 March 9, 2018 Accell Group N.V. presentation annual results 2017 1

More information

Decision-Making under the Gambler s Fallacy:

Decision-Making under the Gambler s Fallacy: Decision-Making under the Gambler s Fallacy: Evidence from Asylum Judges, Loan Officers, and Baseball Umpires Daniel Chen 1 Tobias Moskowitz 2 Kelly Shue 2 1 ETH Zurich 2 University of Chicago, Booth School

More information

Ups and Downs: Team Performance in Best-of-Seven Playoff Series

Ups and Downs: Team Performance in Best-of-Seven Playoff Series Ups and Downs: Team Performance in Best-of-Seven Playoff Series Tim B. Swartz, Aruni Tennakoon, Farouk Nathoo, Parminder S. Sarohia and Min Tsao Abstract This paper explores the impact of the status of

More information

This article appeared in a journal published by Elsevier. The attached copy is furnished to the author for internal non-commercial research and

This article appeared in a journal published by Elsevier. The attached copy is furnished to the author for internal non-commercial research and This article appeared in a journal published by Elsevier. The attached copy is furnished to the author for internal non-commercial research and education use, including for instruction at the authors institution

More information

Golfers in Colorado: The Role of Golf in Recreational and Tourism Lifestyles and Expenditures

Golfers in Colorado: The Role of Golf in Recreational and Tourism Lifestyles and Expenditures Golfers in Colorado: The Role of Golf in Recreational and Tourism Lifestyles and Expenditures by Josh Wilson, Phil Watson, Dawn Thilmany and Steve Davies Graduate Research Assistants, Associate Professor

More information

Bookmaker and pari-mutuel betting: Is a (reverse) favourite-longshot bias built-in?

Bookmaker and pari-mutuel betting: Is a (reverse) favourite-longshot bias built-in? Bookmaker and pari-mutuel betting: Is a (reverse) favourite-longshot bias built-in? Alexander K. Koch a,b and Hui-Fai Shing a a Royal Holloway, University of London and b IZA November 26, 2007 Abstract

More information

a) List and define all assumptions for multiple OLS regression. These are all listed in section 6.5

a) List and define all assumptions for multiple OLS regression. These are all listed in section 6.5 Prof. C. M. Dalton ECN 209A Spring 2015 Practice Problems (After HW1, HW2, before HW3) CORRECTED VERSION Question 1. Draw and describe a relationship with heteroskedastic errors. Support your claim with

More information

The Simple Linear Regression Model ECONOMETRICS (ECON 360) BEN VAN KAMMEN, PHD

The Simple Linear Regression Model ECONOMETRICS (ECON 360) BEN VAN KAMMEN, PHD The Simple Linear Regression Model ECONOMETRICS (ECON 360) BEN VAN KAMMEN, PHD Outline Definition. Deriving the Estimates. Properties of the Estimates. Units of Measurement and Functional Form. Expected

More information

Economics of Sport (ECNM 10068)

Economics of Sport (ECNM 10068) Economics of Sport (ECNM 10068) Lecture 7: Theories of a League - Part I Carl Singleton 1 The University of Edinburgh 6th March 2018 1 Carl.Singleton@ed.ac.uk 1 / 27 2 / 27 Theories of a League - Part

More information

Using Sports Wagering Markets to Evaluate and Compare Team Winning Streaks in Sports

Using Sports Wagering Markets to Evaluate and Compare Team Winning Streaks in Sports American Journal of Operations Research, 2015, 5, 357-366 Published Online September 2015 in SciRes. http://www.scirp.org/journal/ajor http://dx.doi.org/10.4236/ajor.2015.55029 Using Sports Wagering Markets

More information

Citation for published version (APA): Canudas Romo, V. (2003). Decomposition Methods in Demography Groningen: s.n.

Citation for published version (APA): Canudas Romo, V. (2003). Decomposition Methods in Demography Groningen: s.n. University of Groningen Decomposition Methods in Demography Canudas Romo, Vladimir IMPORTANT NOTE: You are advised to consult the publisher's version (publisher's PDF) if you wish to cite from it. Please

More information

A SURVEY OF 1997 COLORADO ANGLERS AND THEIR WILLINGNESS TO PAY INCREASED LICENSE FEES

A SURVEY OF 1997 COLORADO ANGLERS AND THEIR WILLINGNESS TO PAY INCREASED LICENSE FEES Executive Summary of research titled A SURVEY OF 1997 COLORADO ANGLERS AND THEIR WILLINGNESS TO PAY INCREASED LICENSE FEES Conducted by USDA Forest Service Rocky Mountain Research Station Fort Collins,

More information

A CHOICE MODEL ON TRIP MODE CHAIN FOR INTER-ISLANDS COMMUTERS IN MOLUCCA-INDONESIA: A CASE STUDY OF THE TERNATE ISLAND HALMAHERA ISLAND TRIP

A CHOICE MODEL ON TRIP MODE CHAIN FOR INTER-ISLANDS COMMUTERS IN MOLUCCA-INDONESIA: A CASE STUDY OF THE TERNATE ISLAND HALMAHERA ISLAND TRIP International Journal of Civil Engineering and Technology (IJCIET) Volume 8, Issue 7, July 2017, pp. 1050 1057, Article ID: IJCIET_08_07_112 Available online at http://http://ww www.iaeme.com/ijciet/issues.asp?jtype=ijciet&v

More information

Diachronic Dutch Books and Sleeping Beauty. One version of the Sleeping Beauty problem (Elga 2000) is this: Beauty is the subject of an

Diachronic Dutch Books and Sleeping Beauty. One version of the Sleeping Beauty problem (Elga 2000) is this: Beauty is the subject of an Diachronic Dutch Books and Sleeping Beauty One version of the Sleeping Beauty problem (Elga 2000) is this: Beauty is the subject of an experiment that begins when she is put to sleep on Sunday night. She

More information

Birkbeck Sport Business Centre. Research Paper Series. A review of measures of competitive balance in the analysis of competitive balance literature

Birkbeck Sport Business Centre. Research Paper Series. A review of measures of competitive balance in the analysis of competitive balance literature ISSN: 1756-8811 Birkbeck Sport Business Centre Research Paper Series A review of measures of competitive balance in the analysis of competitive balance literature Richard Evans Birkbeck, University of

More information

Framing Effects in the Field: Evidence from Two Million Bets

Framing Effects in the Field: Evidence from Two Million Bets : Evidence from Two Million Bets Alasdair Brown University of East Anglia Fuyu Yang University of East Anglia November 6, 2017 We would like to thank Amrish Patel and Bob Sugden for very helpful comments.

More information

Efficiency Wages in Major League Baseball Starting. Pitchers Greg Madonia

Efficiency Wages in Major League Baseball Starting. Pitchers Greg Madonia Efficiency Wages in Major League Baseball Starting Pitchers 1998-2001 Greg Madonia Statement of Problem Free agency has existed in Major League Baseball (MLB) since 1974. This is a mechanism that allows

More information

Home Team Advantage in English Premier League

Home Team Advantage in English Premier League Patrice Marek* and František Vávra** *European Centre of Excellence NTIS New Technologies for the Information Society, Faculty of Applied Sciences, University of West Bohemia, Czech Republic: patrke@kma.zcu.cz

More information

Stats 2002: Probabilities for Wins and Losses of Online Gambling

Stats 2002: Probabilities for Wins and Losses of Online Gambling Abstract: Jennifer Mateja Andrea Scisinger Lindsay Lacher Stats 2002: Probabilities for Wins and Losses of Online Gambling The objective of this experiment is to determine whether online gambling is a

More information

Measuring Returns to Scale in Nineteenth-Century French Industry Technical Appendix

Measuring Returns to Scale in Nineteenth-Century French Industry Technical Appendix Measuring Returns to Scale in Nineteenth-Century French Industry Technical Appendix Ulrich Doraszelski Hoover Institution, Stanford University March 2004 Formal Derivations Gross-output vs value-added

More information

CHAPTER 10 TOTAL RECREATIONAL FISHING DAMAGES AND CONCLUSIONS

CHAPTER 10 TOTAL RECREATIONAL FISHING DAMAGES AND CONCLUSIONS CHAPTER 10 TOTAL RECREATIONAL FISHING DAMAGES AND CONCLUSIONS 10.1 INTRODUCTION This chapter provides the computation of the total value of recreational fishing service flow losses (damages) through time

More information

Kobe University Repository : Kernel

Kobe University Repository : Kernel Kobe University Repository : Kernel タイトル Title 著者 Author(s) 掲載誌 巻号 ページ Citation 刊行日 Issue date 資源タイプ Resource Type 版区分 Resource Version 権利 Rights Lock! Risk-Free Arbitrage in the Japanese Racetrack Betting

More information

1. OVERVIEW OF METHOD

1. OVERVIEW OF METHOD 1. OVERVIEW OF METHOD The method used to compute tennis rankings for Iowa girls high school tennis http://ighs-tennis.com/ is based on the Elo rating system (section 1.1) as adopted by the World Chess

More information

Round Numbers as Goals Evidence From Baseball, SAT Takers, and the Lab

Round Numbers as Goals Evidence From Baseball, SAT Takers, and the Lab University of Pennsylvania ScholarlyCommons Operations, Information and Decisions Papers Wharton Faculty Research 1-2011 Round Numbers as Goals Evidence From Baseball, SAT Takers, and the Lab Devin Pope

More information

Elsevier fm-n50744.pdf 2008/5/17 6:52 pm Page: i Trim: 7.5in 9.25in Floats: Top/Bot TS: diacritech, India HANDBOOK OF SPORTS AND LOTTERY MARKETS

Elsevier fm-n50744.pdf 2008/5/17 6:52 pm Page: i Trim: 7.5in 9.25in Floats: Top/Bot TS: diacritech, India HANDBOOK OF SPORTS AND LOTTERY MARKETS Elsevier fm-n50744.pdf 2008/5/17 6:52 pm Page: i Trim: 7.5in 9.25in Floats: Top/Bot TS: diacritech, India HANDBOOK OF SPORTS AND LOTTERY MARKETS Elsevier fm-n50744.pdf 2008/5/17 6:52 pm Page: ii Trim:

More information

CONTENTS SPORTS BETTING 101 TYPES OF SPORTS WAGERS WELCOME TO IMPORTANT TERMS GLOSSARY FOOTBALL BASKETBALL BASEBALL HOCKEY SOCCER BOXING/MMA

CONTENTS SPORTS BETTING 101 TYPES OF SPORTS WAGERS WELCOME TO IMPORTANT TERMS GLOSSARY FOOTBALL BASKETBALL BASEBALL HOCKEY SOCCER BOXING/MMA HOW TO BET GUIDE WELCOME TO SPORTS BETTING 101 TYPES OF SPORTS WAGERS STRAIGHT BET A straight bet is an individual wager on a game or event that will be determined by a point spread, money line or total.

More information

Robust specification testing in regression: the FRESET test and autocorrelated disturbances

Robust specification testing in regression: the FRESET test and autocorrelated disturbances Robust specification testing in regression: the FRESET test and autocorrelated disturbances Linda F. DeBenedictis and David E. A. Giles * Policy and Research Division, Ministry of Human Resources, 614

More information

CS 5306 INFO 5306: Crowdsourcing and. Human Computation. Lecture 11. 9/28/17 Haym Hirsh

CS 5306 INFO 5306: Crowdsourcing and. Human Computation. Lecture 11. 9/28/17 Haym Hirsh CS 5306 INFO 5306: Crowdsourcing and Human Computation Lecture 11 9/28/17 Haym Hirsh Upcoming Speakers Thursday, Aug 31, 4:15 (after class) Louis Hyman. The Return of The Independent Workforce: The History

More information

Explaining the Favorite Long Shot Bias: Is it Risk-Love or Misperceptions?

Explaining the Favorite Long Shot Bias: Is it Risk-Love or Misperceptions? Explaining the Favorite Long Shot Bias: Is it Risk-Love or Misperceptions? Erik Snowberg California Institute of Technology Justin Wolfers University of Pennsylvania, Centre for Economic Policy Research,

More information

College Teaching Methods & Styles Journal First Quarter 2007 Volume 3, Number 1

College Teaching Methods & Styles Journal First Quarter 2007 Volume 3, Number 1 The Economics Of The Duration Of The Baseball World Series Alexander E. Cassuto, (E-mail: aleaxander.cassuto@csueastbay.edu), California State University, Hayward Franklin Lowenthal, (E-mail: frabklin.lowenthal@csueastbay.edu),

More information

Explaining the Favorite-Longshot Bias: Is it Risk-Love, or Misperceptions?

Explaining the Favorite-Longshot Bias: Is it Risk-Love, or Misperceptions? Explaining the Favorite-Longshot Bias: Is it Risk-Love, or Misperceptions? Erik Snowberg Stanford GSB snowberg_erik@gsb.stanford.edu Justin Wolfers The Wharton School, U.Penn CEPR, IZA, & NBER jwolfers@wharton.upenn.edu

More information

ECO 199 GAMES OF STRATEGY Spring Term 2004 Precept Materials for Week 3 February 16, 17

ECO 199 GAMES OF STRATEGY Spring Term 2004 Precept Materials for Week 3 February 16, 17 ECO 199 GAMES OF STRATEGY Spring Term 2004 Precept Materials for Week 3 February 16, 17 Illustration of Rollback in a Decision Problem, and Dynamic Games of Competition Here we discuss an example whose

More information

Running head: DATA ANALYSIS AND INTERPRETATION 1

Running head: DATA ANALYSIS AND INTERPRETATION 1 Running head: DATA ANALYSIS AND INTERPRETATION 1 Data Analysis and Interpretation Final Project Vernon Tilly Jr. University of Central Oklahoma DATA ANALYSIS AND INTERPRETATION 2 Owners of the various

More information

A Fair Target Score Calculation Method for Reduced-Over One day and T20 International Cricket Matches

A Fair Target Score Calculation Method for Reduced-Over One day and T20 International Cricket Matches A Fair Target Score Calculation Method for Reduced-Over One day and T20 International Cricket Matches Rohan de Silva, PhD. Abstract In one day internationals and T20 cricket games, the par score is defined

More information

Predicting the Total Number of Points Scored in NFL Games

Predicting the Total Number of Points Scored in NFL Games Predicting the Total Number of Points Scored in NFL Games Max Flores (mflores7@stanford.edu), Ajay Sohmshetty (ajay14@stanford.edu) CS 229 Fall 2014 1 Introduction Predicting the outcome of National Football

More information

2010 TRAVEL TIME REPORT

2010 TRAVEL TIME REPORT CASUALTY ACTUARIAL SOCIETY EDUCATION POLICY COMMITTEE 2010 TRAVEL TIME REPORT BIENNIAL REPORT TO THE BOARD OF DIRECTORS ON TRAVEL TIME STATISTICS FOR CANDIDATES OF THE CASUALTY ACTUARIAL SOCIETY June 2011

More information

Will it offer a worthwhile return on investment for operators seeking growth in new markets? GO OR NO GO?

Will it offer a worthwhile return on investment for operators seeking growth in new markets? GO OR NO GO? Will it offer a worthwhile return on investment for operators seeking growth in new markets? GO OR NO GO? Introduction Big picture of french online gaming market Main issues on french online gaming market

More information

Blockholders, Market E ciency, and Managerial Myopia

Blockholders, Market E ciency, and Managerial Myopia Blockholders, Market E ciency, and Managerial Myopia Alex Edmans, Wharton Notre Dame Finance Seminar October 12, 2007 Alex Edmans Blockholders, E ciency, and Myopia October 12, 2007 1 Introduction This

More information

Consumer Preferences, Ecolabels, and Effects of Negative Environmental Information By Xianwen Chen, Frode Alfnes and Kyrre Rickertsen

Consumer Preferences, Ecolabels, and Effects of Negative Environmental Information By Xianwen Chen, Frode Alfnes and Kyrre Rickertsen Consumer Preferences, Ecolabels, and Effects of Negative Environmental Information By Xianwen Chen, Frode Alfnes and Kyrre Rickertsen School of Economics and Business Norwegian University of Life Sciences

More information

Evaluating the Influence of R3 Treatments on Fishing License Sales in Pennsylvania

Evaluating the Influence of R3 Treatments on Fishing License Sales in Pennsylvania Evaluating the Influence of R3 Treatments on Fishing License Sales in Pennsylvania Prepared for the: Pennsylvania Fish and Boat Commission Produced by: PO Box 6435 Fernandina Beach, FL 32035 Tel (904)

More information