Great Depressions of the Twentieth Century Project

Similar documents
What Can We Learn From the Current Crisis in Argentina?

The U.S. Economic Recovery: Why so weak and what should be done? William J. Crowder Ph.D.

Seven Lean Years Explaining Persistent Global Economic Weakness

From Recession to Recovery

The structure of the euro area recovery

This Time is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly

Paul Bingham Managing Director, Global Trade and Transportation February 18, 2009

The Aftermath of Global Financial Crises

The Rise of China and Breaking out the Middle- Income Trap in Latin America and the Caribbean countries: A New Structural Economics Approach

Macroeconomics I 22104, Fall Isaac Baley. Introduction

U.S. Overview. Gathering Steam? Tuesday, October 1, 2013

RISI EUROPEAN CONFERENCE. (Barcelona, 6 March 2018) The European Economy Things look good just now. Can this last?

The World and U.S. Economy and San Pedro Bay Container Trade Outlook Forecast Review

The Economic Outlook. Economic Policy Division

Grasshoppers, Ants and Locusts: the future of the world economy

Labor Markets. Chris Edmond NYU Stern. Spring 2007

Deficit Reduction and Economic Growth: Are They Mutually Exclusive Goals? Tuesday, May 1, 2012; 2:30 PM - 3:45 PM

FIVE GREAT STAGNATIONS

The U. S. Economic Outlook: Robert J. Gordon

MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICIES DURING THE NEXT RECESSION

The U.S. & Global Economic Outlook Greg Ip, U.S. Economics Editor, The Economist Remarks to The American Sportfishing Association

Canadian Teleconference: Can the Canadian Economy Survive the Turmoil in the United States?

Outlook 2008/09 Life In the Aftermath of the Great Global Credit Crisis. May 8 th, Presented by:

Panel on Post-Crisis Growth Performance Determinants, Effects and Policy Implications

Economic Outlook March Economic Policy Division

China from a Macroeconomist s Perspective. Kim J. Ruhl

Trade and Economic Trends

Why Is the Recovery from the Financial Crisis So Sluggish?

Bob Costello Chief Economist & Vice President American Trucking Associations. Economic & Motor Carrier Industry Update.

Introduction to Topics in Macroeconomics 2

Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, FIRM (Financial Institution Relationship Management)

Retrenchment or Stagnation: Lessons from Japan s Lost Decades. Andrew Smithers. UK-Japan 21 st Century Group Conference 3 rd May, 2013

Unbacked Fiscal Expansion: 1933 America & Contemporary Japan

ABA Commercial Real Estate Lending Committee

The Shifts and the Shocks Martin Wolf, Associate Editor & Chief Economics Commentator, Financial Times

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA Economics 134 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Spring 2018 Professor David Romer

RBC Economics Financial Update Dawn Desjardins

The Eurozone integration, des-integration and possible future developments

Reading the Tea Leaves: Investing for 2010 and Beyond

The Economic Outlook. Economic Policy Division

Telling Canada s story in numbers Elizabeth Richards Analytical Studies Branch April 20, 2017

The U.S. Economic Outlook

The Changing Global Economy Impacts on Seaports and Trade Dr. Walter Kemmsies

The Ongoing Recession: How Long and How Deep? Robert J. Gordon Northwestern University and NBER BAC Meeting October 22, 2008

Global economy maintaining solid growth momentum. Canada leading the pack

2019 ECONOMIC FORECAST AND FINANCIAL MARKET UPDATE

The Herzliya Conference The Economic Dimension Prof. Rafi Melnick Provost, Interdisciplinary Center (IDC) Herzliya

Discussion of: The Rise, the Fall, and the Resurrection of Iceland by Benediksdottir, Eggertsson, Þorarinsson. Jón Steinsson Columbia University

Lessons from NAFTA for Latin American and Caribbean Countries. World Bank January

Session 4. Growth. The World Economy Share of Global GDP Year 2011 (PPP)

Outline. Overview of globalization. Global outlook for real economic activity & inflation. Risks to the outlook

Future Global Trade Trends - Risks & Opportunities. Pulse of the Ports: Peak Season Forecast March 21, 2013

Understanding the. Dr. Christopher Waller. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Government finances A long term assessment. Presented by Edwina Matos Pereira

The productivity puzzle: why improving labour productivity is critical for Europe s economic (and political) stability

Wenlin Liu, Senior Economist. Stateof Wyoming. Economic Analysis Division State of Wyoming 1

Global trade: how does it look?

US imports from emerging economies have grown rapidly

Economic Analysis What s happening with U.S. potential GDP growth?

Global Economic Outlook: From Fiscal Cliff to Rushcliffe in 15 minutes. Tom Rogers. Lead Economist, Oxford Economics.

By making use of SAFRIM (South African Inter-Industry Macro-Economic Model) By Jeaunes Viljoen, Conningarth Economists, 1

The Herzliya Indices. National Security Balance The Civilian Quantitative Dimension. Herzliya Conference Prof. Rafi Melnick, IDC Herzliya

Economic & Financial Market Outlook

Henley Global Masterclasses 2017 Henley Business School, Greenlands, Henley-on-Thames Friday 12 May 2017

THE ICELANDIC ECONOMY AN IMPRESSIVE RECOVERY BUT WHAT CHALLENGES LIE AHEAD?

Global Economic Outlook

As Good as it Gets. The Aging Expansion Powers On... but for How Much Longer? Andrew J. Nelson Chief Economist USA, Colliers International

Financial Stability Implications of Changing Global Finance: Policy Panel Global Finance in Transition

SA economic review Kevin Lings. August 2018

National Transfer Accounts in Mexico

Comment on: Productivity Growth, Wage Growth and Unions by Kügler, Schönberg and Schreiner

U.S. AUTO INDUSTRY UPDATE Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Automotive Outlook Symposium. Emily Kolinski Morris Chief Economist May 2015

Inequality in America : The 1% in International and Historical Perspective

National and Regional Economic Outlook. Central Southern CAA Conference

Better in than out? Economic performance inside and outside the European monetary union. Roma, Rapporto Europa 2015

Muhlenkamp & Company. Webcast August 30, Ron Muhlenkamp, Portfolio Manager Jeff Muhlenkamp, Portfolio Manager Tony Muhlenkamp, President

Business Cycles. Chris Edmond NYU Stern. Spring 2007

Can Manufacturing Still be a Driver of

Major Issues and Trends Facing the Port and Marine Transportation Industry

An early warning system to predict house price bubbles

The U.S. Economic Outlook

GLOBAL ECONOMICS, REAL ESTATE PRICING & OUTLOOK FOR 2017 RICHARD BARKHAM GLOBAL CHIEF ECONOMIST

sector: recent developments VÍTOR CONSTÂNCIO

Maximizing Tourism Marketing Investments A Canadian Perspective

Economic Transformation and Recovery in Hong Kong and Singapore

CALIFORNIA STATE UNIVERSITY LONG BEACH. Southern California Regional Economic Forecast

Opportunities in a Challenging Global Business Environment: Can the World Avoid a Double-Dip?

Abel M. Mateus Universidade Nova de Lisboa

The Global Economy: Sustaining Momentum

France : Economic developments and reforms, where are we heading?

Forecast evaluation report Robert Chote Chairman

Economic Outlook for Canada: Economy Confronting Capacity Limits

Trade Growth - Fundamental Driver of Port Operations and Development Strategies

Quantifying the Lasting Harm to the U.S. Economy from the Financial Crisis

RISI LATIN AMERICAN CONFERENCE. (São Paulo, 16 August 2016) The Latin American Economy: Some Successes, Many Disappointments

The U.S. Economy How Serious A Downturn? Nigel Gault Group Managing Director North American Macroeconomic Services

A Primer on Factors Affecting Farmland Values

Livio Di Matteo, Lakehead University Talk Prepared for the Thunder Bay (Port Arthur) Rotary, November 27 th, 2018

A comment on recent events, and...

Texas Housing Markets: Metropolitan vs. Border Communities. September 22, 2014

Transcription:

Great Depressions of the Twentieth Century Project Timothy J. Kehoe and Edward C. Prescott www.greatdepressionsbook.com

Cole and Ohanian, The Great Depression in the United States from a Neoclassical Perspective, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, Winter 1999. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Conference, October 2000. Special Issue of Review of Economic Dynamics, January 2002. Great Depressions of the Twentieth Century, July 2007.

15 studies by 26 researchers using the same methodology Great depressions 1930s United States, United Kingdom, Canada, France, Germany Recent Argentina (1970s and 1980s), Chile and Mexico (1980s), Brazil (1980s and 1990s), New Zealand and Switzerland (1970s, 1980s, and 1990s), Argentina (1998-2002) Not-quite-great depressions Italy (1930s), Finland (1990s), Japan (1990s)

Kehoe and Prescott define a great depression to be a large negative deviation from balanced growth. They set the growth rate in the balanced growth path to be 2 percent per year, the growth rate of output per working-age person in the United States during the twentieth century.

Real GDP per Working Age Person in the United States, 1900-2009 3.00 800 2.00 400 index (1900 = 100) 1.00 200 trend real GDP 0.00 100-1.00 50 1900 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 year

Trend growth: i t i yˆt yˆ0, 1.02 Great depression: D [ t, t ] such that 0 1 1. There is some t in D in such that i t t0 i y ˆ t yt 2. There is some t t0 10 / 1 0.20. 0 such that i t t0 i y t yt 3. There are no t 1, t 2 in D, t2 t1 10, such that i t2 t / 1 i y t y 1 0. 2 t 1 / 1 0.15. 0

Great depressions in the 1930s: Detrended output per person 110 100 France Germany Index (1928 = 100) 90 80 70 60 United States Canada 50 1928 1930 1932 1934 1936 1938

Great depressions in the 1980s: Detrended output per working-age person 110 100 Index (1980 = 100) 90 80 70 Brazil Mexico Chile 60 Argentina 50 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990

Great depressions methodology Crucial elements: Growth accounting and dynamic general equilibrium model Growth accounting decomposes changes in output per working-age person into three factors: a productivity factor a capital factor an hours-worked factor

Great depressions methodology Crucial elements: Growth accounting and dynamic general equilibrium model Growth accounting decomposes changes in output per working-age person into three factors: a productivity factor a capital factor an hours-worked factor Keynesian analysis stresses declines in inputs of capital and labor as the causes of depressions.

Balanced growth path In the dynamic general equilibrium model, if the productivity factor grows at a constant rate, then the capital factor and the hours-worked factor stay constant and growth in output is due to growth in the productivity factor. Twentieth century U.S. macro data are very close to a balanced growth path, with the exception of the Great Depression and the subsequent World War II build-up.

Balanced growth path t 1 1 1 t At t t t t Y K L N Y N When 1 A t 1 g At K L t Y and t t Nt are constant Y t N t grows at rate g 1, assume g 1 0.02 as in U.S.

Growth Accounting for the United States 1970-2009 200 180 output index (1970 = 100) 160 140 120 100 80 hours worked capital productivity 60 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005

Growth accounting for the United States 1929 1939 140 120 capital productivity index (1929=100) 100 80 output hours worked 60 1929 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939

We use a dynamic general equilibrium model to model the responses of households and firms in terms of capital accumulation and hours worked to changes in productivity and changes in government policy. We take the path of the productivity factor as exogenous. Comparing the results of the model with the data, we can identify features of the depression that need further analysis. Example: The Great Depression in the United States.

Growth accounting for the United States 140 120 capital productivity index (1929=100) 100 80 output hours worked 60 1929 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939

Growth accounting for the United States 140 120 productivity index (1929=100) 100 80 60 1929 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939

Growth accounting for the United States 140 120 index (1929=100) 100 80 output 60 1929 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939

Growth accounting for the United States 140 120 capital index (1929=100) 100 80 60 1929 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939

Growth accounting for the United States 140 120 index (1929=100) 100 80 hours worked 60 1929 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939

Conclusions A simple dynamic general equilibrium model that takes movements in the productivity factor as exogenous can explain most of the 1929-1933 downturn in the United States. The model over predicts the increase in hours worked during the 1933-1939 recovery. Need for Further Study The decline in productivity 1929-1933 The failure of hours worked to recover 1933-1939

Lessons from Great Depressions Project The main determinants of depressions are not drops in the inputs of capital and labor stressed in traditional theories of depressions but rather drops in the efficiency with which these inputs are used, measured as total factor productivity (TFP). Exogenous shocks like the deteriorations in the terms of trade and the increases in foreign interest rates that buffeted Chile and Mexico in the early 1980s can cause a decline in economic activity of the usual business cycle magnitude. Misguided government policy can turn such a decline into a severe and prolonged drop in economic activity below trend a great depression.

Growth Accounting for Mexico 140 120 capital index (1980 = 100) 100 hours output 80 productivity 60 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005

A Decade Lost and Found: Mexico and Chile in the 1980s Raphael Bergoeing, Patrick J. Kehoe, Timothy J. Kehoe, and Raimundo Soto Similar crises in 1981-1983 more severe in Chile than in Mexico Different recoveries much faster in Chile than in Mexico Why different pattern?

Real GDP per working-age (15-64) person detrended by 2 percent per year 130 120 index (1980=100) 110 100 90 80 70 Chile Mexico 60 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 year

Growth accounting and applied dynamic general equilibrium model Two numerical experiments with model: Base case model: takes series for productivity factor as given. Model with tax reform: takes series for productivity factor as given and imposes tax reform that lowers tax on capital income in 1988 in both countries.

Applied dynamic general equilibrium model The representative consumer maximizes subject to t log (1 )log( ) t C 1980 t hnt Lt C K K wl ( )( r ) K T t t 1 t t t 1 t t t t where T ( r ) K is a lump-sum transfer. t t t t Feasibility: 1 t t 1 t t t t. C K ( 1 ) K AK L

First order conditions: 1 C Look at 1960-1980 data t 1 Calibration 1 ( 1 )( r ) C t t t w hn L C 1 t t t t C C ( r ) C t t 1 Ct 0.30 in Mexico, 0.28 in Chile. C w( hn L) 0.98, 1 t t 1 0.45 in Mexico, 0.56 in Chile t t t t. ;

Numerical experiments Base case: 0.45 in Mexico, 0.56 in Chile, 1980-2000. t t Tax reform: 0.45 in Mexico, 0.56 in Chile, 1980-1988; t t 0.12 in Mexico, 0.12 in Chile, 1988-2000. t t

Detrended real GDP per working-age person and productivity factor 140 120 Chile output index (1980=100) 100 80 60 Chile productivity Mexico output 40 Mexico productivity 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000

Detrended real GDP per working-age person: base case model 140 120 Chile data index (1980=100) 100 80 60 Chile model Mexico data 40 Mexico model 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000

Detrended real GDP per working-age person: model with tax refrom 140 Chile model index (1980=100) 120 100 80 60 Chile data Mexico data Mexico model 40 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000

What do we learn from growth accounting and numerical experiments? Nearly all of the differences in the recoveries in Mexico and Chile result from different paths of productivity. Tax reforms are important in explaining some features of the recoveries, but not the differences. Implications for studying structural reforms story: Only reforms that are promising as explanations are those that show up primarily as differences in productivity, not those that show up as differences in factor inputs. Timing of reforms is crucial if they are to drive the differences in economic performance.

Chile: tax reforms 1975, 1984 social security reform 1980 fiscal surpluses Fiscal reforms Mexico: tax reforms 1980, 1985, 1987, 1989 fiscal deficits Important, but not for explaining the differences!

Trade reforms Chile: by 1979 all quantitative restrictions eliminated uniform tariff of 10 percent tariff hikes during crisis tariff back below 10 percent in 1991 Mexico: in 1985 100 percent of domestic production protected by import licenses nontariff barriers and dual exchange rates Massive trade reforms in Mexico 1987-1994, culminating in NAFTA Timing seems wrong!

Privatization Chile major privatizations 1974-1979 Mexico major nationalization 1982 expropriated banks holdings of private companies government controlled 60-80 percent of GDP major privatizations after 1989 Timing seems wrong?

Banking Chile: 1982 and after took over failed banks market-determined interest rates lowered reserve requirements. Mexico: 1982 and after nationalized all banks government set low deposit rates 75 percent of loans either to government or directed by government.

Private credit as a percent of GDP 90 80 70 Chile percent GDP 60 50 40 30 Mexico 20 10 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 year

Bankruptcy laws Chile had reformed the administration of its bankruptcy procedures in 1978. In 1982 it reformed its bankruptcy laws to look much like those in the United States. Mexico reformed its bankruptcy procedures in a similar way only in 2000. (Maybe not so similarly!)

Business bankruptcies in Chile 500 400 number per year 300 200 100 0 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 year

Studying the experience of countries that have experienced great depressions during the twentieth century teaches us that massive public interventions in the economy to maintain employment and investment during a financial crisis can, if they distort incentives enough, lead to a great depression.

Comparison of the 2007 2010 U.S. recession with the 1981 1983 U.S. recession

U.S. Real GDP 106 104 index (peak = 100) 102 100 98 96 2007 IV 1981 III 94 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 quarter following peak

U.S. Unemployment Rate 12.0 10.0 July 1981 8.0 percent 6.0 4.0 December 2007 2.0 0.0 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 month following peak

Comparison of the 2007 2009 U.S. recession with the 1981 1983 U.S. recession Using conventional measures real GDP, unemployment rate the 2007 2010 recession is not noticeably worse than the 1981 1983 recession.

Comparison of the 2007 2009 U.S. recession with the 1981 1983 U.S. recession Using conventional measures real GDP, unemployment rate the 2007 2010 recession is not noticeably worse than the 1981 1983 recession. The recovery during the 2007 2010 recession has been slower, and there is still a danger that the current recession could turn into a double-dip recession.

What about growth accounting?

Growth Accounting, 1981-1983 Recession 108 106 index (1981 III = 100) 104 102 100 98 96 94 output capital productivity hours worked 92 90 88 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 quarter following peak

Growth Accounting, 2007-2009 Recession 108 106 productivity index (2007 IV = 100) 104 102 100 98 96 94 capital output 92 hours worked 90 88 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 quarter following peak

What about growth accounting? The 1981-1983 recession(s) is an example of the standard real business cycle downturn, where the driving force is a drop in productivity. The current recession is different. This warrants further research.

What did we economists do wrong? If the risk of a fall in housing prices had been understood and priced correctly, higher interest rates on lending for construction projects and mortgages would have corrected the problem. The lack of understanding of systemic risk on the part of banks, regulators, and bond ratings agencies calls for reform and, perhaps, new regulations.

What did we economists do wrong? If the risk of a fall in housing prices had been understood and priced correctly, higher interest rates on lending for construction projects and mortgages would have corrected the problem. The lack of understanding of systemic risk on the part of banks, regulators, and bond ratings agencies calls for reform and, perhaps, new regulations. Mistakes like this happen. We cannot be constantly over regulating our economy to prevent the previous crisis from occurring again.

What did we economists do right? Kareken-Wallace and Stern-Feldman: Efficiently allocating risk requires that any insurance should be accompanied by regulation. Any institution that is too big to fail needs to be regulated. Kehoe-Prescott (and others!): We need to study crises of the past to be prepared to deal with them in the future.

Those who try to justify the sorts of Keynesian policies implemented by the Mexican government in the 1980s often quote Keynes s dictum from A Tract on Monetary Reform: The long run is a misleading guide to current affairs. In the long run we are all dead.

Studying past great depressions turns this dictum on its head: If we do not consider the consequences of policy for productivity, in the long run we could all be in a great depression.